NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
EMIGRATION DURING THE FRENCH REVOLUTION:
CONSEQUENCES IN THE SHORT AND LONGUE DURÉE
Raphaël Franck
Stelios Michalopoulos
Working Paper 23936
http://www.nber.org/papers/w23936
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
October 2017
We would like to thank Sascha Becker, Davide Cantoni, Guillaume Daudin, Melissa Dell, Oded
Galor, Paola Giuliano, Moshe Hazan, Ruixue Jia, Oren Levintal, Omer Moav, Ben Olken, Elias
Papaioannou, Gerard Roland, Nico Voigtlaender, David Weil, and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya as well
as seminar participants at Brown, Harvard, Harvard Kennedy School of Government, Hebrew
University of Jerusalem, NBER Summer Institute Political Economy & Income Distribution and
Macroeconomics Workshop, Northwestern Kellogg, Paris-1, Princeton, Insead, NUS, Hong Kong
University of Science and Technology, Sciences-Po, Tel Aviv, IDC Herzliya, Toronto, Warwick,
and conference participants at the European Public Choice Society Meeting, the Israeli Economic
Association conference, and the Warwick/Princeton conference for valuable suggestions. We
thank Bernard Bodinier, Martin Fiszbein, and Nico Voigtlaender for sharing their data. We would
also like to thank Nicholas Reynolds for superlative research assistance. All errors are our own
responsibility. Stelios Michalopoulos and Raphael Franck have no relevant financial support to
disclose in relationship to this project. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do
not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been
peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies
official NBER publications.
© 2017 by Raphaël Franck and Stelios Michalopoulos. All rights reserved. Short sections of text,
not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full
credit, including © notice, is given to the source.
Emigration during the French Revolution: Consequences in the Short and Longue Durée
Raphaël Franck and Stelios Michalopoulos
NBER Working Paper No. 23936
October 2017
JEL No. N10,O10,O15
ABSTRACT
During the French Revolution, more than 100,000 individuals, predominantly supporters of the
Old Regime, fled France. As a result, some areas experienced a significant change in the
composition of the local elites whereas in others the pre-revolutionary social structure remained
virtually intact. In this study, we trace the consequences of the émigrés' flight on economic
performance at the local level. We instrument emigration intensity with local temperature shocks
during an inflection point of the Revolution, the summer of 1792, marked by the abolition of the
constitutional monarchy and bouts of local violence. Our findings suggest that émigrés have a
non monotonic effect on comparative development. During the 19th century, there is a significant
negative impact on income per capita, which becomes positive from the second half of the 20th
century onward. This pattern can be partially attributed to the reduction in the share of the landed
elites in high-emigration regions. We show that the resulting fragmentation of agricultural
holdings reduced labor productivity, depressing overall income levels in the short run; however, it
facilitated the rise in human capital investments, eventually leading to a reversal in the pattern of
regional comparative development.
Raphaël Franck
Hebrew University of Jerusalem
Department of Economics
Mount Scopus
Jerusalem 91905
Israel
Stelios Michalopoulos
Brown University
Department of Economics
64 Waterman Street
Providence, RI 02912
and NBER
1 Introduction
Tracing the origins and consequences of major political upheavals occupies an increasing part of
the research agenda among economists and political scientists. The Age of Revolution in Europe
and the Americas, in particular, has received much attention as these major political disruptions
are thought to have shaped the economic and political trajectories of the Western world toward
industrialization and democracy. This broad consensus concerning their paramount importance ,
nevertheless, goes in tandem with a lively debate regarding the exact nature of their consequences.
The voluminous literature on the economic legacy of the French Revolution attests to this.
On the one hand, there is a line of research that highlights its pivotal role in ushering the
French economy into the modern era. This perspective, which begins with 19th century thinkers
of di¤erent persuasions such as Thiers (1823–1827), Guizot (1829-1832), and Marx (1843 [1970])
and is continued during the 20th and 21st centuries by broadly left-leaning scholars (e.g., Jaurès
(1901-1903), Mathiez (1922-1924), Soboul (1962), Hobsbawm (1990), Garrioch (2002), Jones
(2002), and Heller (2006)), views the 1789 French Revolution as the outcome of the long rise
of the bourgeoisie, whose industrial and commercial interests prevailed over those of the landed
aristocracy. These authors, in making their case, stress the bene…ts from the weakening of
the Old Regime as manifested in the abolition of the feudal system, the consolidation of private
property, the simpli…cation of the legal system, and the reduction of traditional controls and scal
hindrances to commerce and industry. However, the scholars, who argue that the reforms brought
about by the French Revolution were conducive to economic growth (e.g., Crouzet (2003)), are
aware of France’s lackluster e conomic performance during the 19th century vis-à-vis England
and Germany, and attribute it to the political upheavals that characterized the country and the
violence of the Revolution and Napoleonic Wars.
On the other hand, mostly liberal or conservative intellectuals (e.g., Taine (1876-1893),
Cobban (1962), Furet (1978), Schama (1989)) emphasize that France remained largely agricul-
tural vis-à-vis England and Germany until 1914. They argue that the French Revolution was
not motivated by di¤erences of economic interests between the nobility and the bourgeoisie, but
was rather a political revolution with social and economic repercussions (Taylor (1967), Aftalion
(1990)).
1
They consider that the French Revolution was actually anticapitalist”contributing to
the persistent agricultural character of France during the 19th century. Besides the cost of war
and civil con‡ict, these studies emphasize the development of an ine¢ cient bureaucracy and the
adverse impact of changes in land holdings on agriculture.
In this study we attempt to shed some light on the short- and long-run economic conse-
1
Maza (2003) in fact argues that there was no genuine French bourgeoisie in 1789 as none of the politicians
deemed to represent the bourgeoisie expressed any consciousness of belonging to such a group.
1
quences of the French Revolution across départements (the administrative divisions of the French
territory). Speci…cally, we exploit local variation in the weakening of the Old Regime, re‡ected in
the di¤erent emigration rates across départements. During the Revolution, more than 100; 000 in-
dividuals emigrated to various European countries and the United States (Greer (1951)). Among
the émigrés, nobles, clergy membe rs, and wealthy landowners were disproportionately repre-
sented.
While the rst émigrés left as early as 1789, the majority actually ed France, during an d
after the summer of 1792 (Taine (1876-1893), Duc de Castries (1966), Bouloiseau (1972), Boisnard
(1992), Tackett (2015)), when the Revolution to ok a radical turn which French historian Georges
Lefebvre has called the Second Revolution”(Lefebvre (1962)). During that summer, following
the arrest of King Louis XVI on August 10 and the September Massacres” in Paris (Caron
(1935), Bluche (1992)), the hitherto uneasy coexistence of the monarchy and the revolutionaries
came to an abrupt end with the proclamation of the Republic on September 21, 1792. Four
months later, King Louis XVI was guillotined.
Our identi…cation strategy exploits local variation in temperature shocks at this in‡ection
point of the French Revolution (i.e., the summer of 1792) to get plausibly exogenous variation in
the rate of emigration across départements. The logic of our instrument rests on a well-developed
argument in the literature on the outbreak of con‡ict that links variations in economic conditions
to the opportunity cost of engaging in violence. To the extent that temperature shocks decrease
agricultural output (which we show to be the case in our historical context), an increase in the
price of wheat (the main staple for the Fren ch in the 18th century)
2
would intensify unrest among
the poorer strata of the population, thereby magnifying emigration among the wealthy supporters
of the moribund monarchy. Consistent with this argument, we show that, in August and Sep-
tember 1792, there were more peasant riots in départements that experienced larger temperature
shocks.
3
It is worth pointing out that the temperature shocks in the summer of 1792 are mild
compared to other years during the Revolution, thereby suggesting that ordinary income u ctua-
tions at critical junctures may have a persistent ect on subsequent development. Importantly,
temperature sho cks during the other years of th e Revolution predict neither emigration rates nor
subsequent economic performance.
Our ndings suggest that émigrés have a nonmonotonic impact on comparative economic
performance unfolding over the subsequent 200 years. Namely, high-emigration départements
have signi…cantly lower GDP per capita during the 19th century but the pattern reverses over
the 20th century. Regarding magnitudes, an increase of half a percentage point in the s hare of
2
On the i mportance of wheat and bread in France in the 18th century, see, for example, Kaplan (1984) and
Kapl an (1996). See also Persson (1999) on grain m arkets during this period.
3
Al ong the same lines, Grosfeld, Sakalli, and Zhuravskaya (2017 ) nd that anti-Jewis h pogroms in eas tern
Europe between 1800 and 1927 occurred w hen poor h arvests coincided wit h institutional and political uncertainty.
2
émigrés in the population of a département (which is the mean emigration rate) decreased GDP
per capita by 12:7% in 1860 but increased it by 8:8% in 2010.
Pinning down the exact mechanism(s) via which emigration shaped local economic per-
formance is challenging. Thanks to the detailed French historical census es, we attempt to shed
some light on this issue. A signi…cant fraction of the émigrés were landowners so their exodus is
likely to have in‡uenced the composition of local landholdings. Using th e agricultural census of
1862, we show that high-emigration départements have fewer large landowners and more small
ones. Indeed, the size of the average farm in France in 1862 was 23:12 acres, smaller than the
average farm of 115 acres in England in 1851 and the average farm of 336:17 acres in the United
States in 1860 (Shaw-Taylor (2005), Fiszbein (2016)).
4
This legacy of fragmented landholdings
has remained largely in place in France to this day. Furthermore we show that, during the 19th
century, this reduction in the preponderance of large private estates and the development of a
small peasantry had a negative impact on agricultural p roductivity by limiting the adoption of
scale-intensive mechanization methods. Moreover, we nd that the share of rich individuals in
the population of high-emigration départements during the 19th century was signi…cantly smaller
compared to regions where few émigrés left. This absence of a critical mass of su¢ ciently wealthy
individuals in the era of capital-intensive modes of production may also explain the slow pace of
industrialization in the h igh-emigration départements during the 19th century.
Interestingly, as early as the midd le of the 19th century, these agriculturally lagging dé-
partements register slightly higher literacy rates than their richer, agriculturally more produc tive
peers. This modest educational edge widens during the early 20th century, after the French state
instituted free and mandatory schooling, eventually translating to higher inc omes per capita in
the later part of the 20th century. This nding h ighlights that historical legacies may crucially
interact with state-level policies and is consistent with recent studies in developing c ountries
which show that increases in agricultural productivity red uce school attendance by increasing
the opp ortunity cost of schooling (see, e.g., Shah and Steinberg (2015)). By establishing a causal
link between the rate of structural transformation across regions in France and the inte nsity of
emigration, we shed new light on an intensely debated topic, that is, the economic legacy of the
1789 Revolution within France.
5
4
In Appe ndix Table D.1, we dis tinguish between French départements and US counties which were above and
below the median value of grain production in 1862 and in 1860, respectively. We a lso provide descriptive statistics
excludi ng French farms below ve hectares an d US farms below ni ne acres so as to focus on farmers who were
presumably above subsistence levels. This robustness check is motivated by the fact that the 1860 US census does
not record plots less than t hree acres. Acro ss all di ¤erent metrics, French farms are signi…cantly smaller than the
US ones.
5
To be sure, violence du ring the French Revolution was rampant and multifaceted. Besides the violence of the
crow ds wh ich our identi…cation strategy leverages, where g roups of people vand alized shops and killed civilians and
po liticians (e.g., Jacques de Fles selle, Jean-Bertra nd Fér au d), Gueney (2011) discusses the top-down planned
annihilation of local populations exemplied by the civil war in the Vene partement, the use of the judi cial
3
Related Literature. Our study relates to the literature on the economic consequences
of revolutions and con‡ict. The latter is voluminous (see, e.g., Blattman and Miguel (2010)
for a thorough review) and usually focuses on the impact of these events on the cumulable
factors of production. Recent studies have shifted their attention to the institutional legacies of
con‡ict. In this respect, our work is closely related to Acemoglu, Cantoni, Joh nson , and Robinson
(2011). The latter explores the impact of institutional reform caused by the French occup ation
of German territories. Consistent with the view that barriers to labor mobility, trade and entry
restrictions were limiting growth in Europe, they nd that French-occupied territories within
Germany eventually experienced faster urbanization rates during the 19th century. In our case, by
focusing on départements within France where the de-jure institutional discontinuities exploited
by Acemoglu, Cantoni, Johnson, and Robinson (2011) are largely absent,
6
we examine whether,
conditional on the nationwide consequences of the radical institutional framework brought forward
by the French Revolution, the local weakening of the Old Regime, re‡ected in the di¤erential
rates of emigration across départements, in‡uenced local development over a signi…cantly longer
horizon. Thus, our study is also closely related to Dell (2012) on the Mexican Revolution. She
nds that land redistribution was more intense across municipalities where insurgent activity was
higher as a result of droughts on the eve of the Revolution, leading to lower economic performance
today. The latter was due to the fact that the Mexican state maintained ultimate control over
the redistributed land known as ejidos.
By looking at the impact of emigration across départements, our study also contributes to
a growing literature that investigates the economic consequences of disruptions in the societal
makeup of a region. Nunn (2008) and Nunn and Wantchekon (2011), for example, explore the
consequences of the slave trade for African countries and groups, whereas Acemoglu, Hassan, and
Robinson (2011) focus on the impact of the mass execution of Jews during the Holocaust on the
subsequent development of Russian cities.
Finally, our res earch is related to studies by Galor and Zeira (1993) and Galor and Moav
(2004), which argue for a nonmonotonic role of equality in the process of development. When
growth is driven by physical capital accumulation, a larger sh are of su¢ ciently wealthy families
would be bene…cial to local growth during the 19th century. However, areas with more evenly
distributed wealth would experience faster human capital accumulation, translating into better
economic outcomes during the 20th and 21st centuries. Consistent with this argument, we show
that the preponderance of small landowners in the high-emigration départements goes in tandem
system to a ssass inate political opponents durin g the Rei gn of Terror, and the war launched against foreign countries.
Unlike the violence of the crowds, these other types of violence do not seem to have responded to climate-induced
temporary income shocks.
6
See, for example, Soboul (1968) for a discussion regarding the application of the Code Civil and t he persistence
of local institut ions within France during the 19th century.
4
with an earlier takeo¤ in human capital accumulation in these regions.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we describe the historical
background on e migration and land redistribution during the French Revolution. In Section 3
we describe the data and our empirical methodology. In Section 4 we present our main ndings
and in Section 5 we discuss some of the potential mechanisms that can account for the observed
pattern. In Section 6 we conclude.
2 Historical Background
In 1789, on the eve of the Revolution, France was the largest economy in Europe, with approxi-
mately 25 million inhabitants and lower wages compared to England (see Labrousse (1933) and
Toutain (1987)). Politically, it was a monarchy where King Louis XVI’s subjects were divided
into three orders: the nobility comprising between 150; 000 and 300; 000 members, the clergy
around 100; 000 members, and the Third Estate (artisans, bankers, lawyers, salesmen, peasants,
etc.) made up the rest. This political structure was to end with the Revolution. In Appendix
A:1 we brie‡y discuss its proximate and ultimate causes.
2.1 Emigration during the French Revolution
The April 8, 1792, law de…ned as émigrés all the individuals absent from the département in
which they possessed property, and, as a result of the July 27, 1792, law, their property could be
seized by the French state. The share of émigrés in the population of each département is our key
independent variable. The data were compiled by Greer (1951) from several original governmental
accounts. The sources are mostly cial publications such as the Liste Générale, par Ordre
Alphabétique, des Emigrés de toute la République (1792-1800) (General List in Alphabetical Order
of Emigrés throughout the Republic), local lists of émigrés, as well as the list of individuals who
received compensation af ter 1825 for the property they lost during the Revolution.
7
Greer (1951)
lists a total of 129; 091 individuals as émigrés.
The revolutionaries were quick to portray all the émigrés as members of the aristocracy who
had prospered on the poverty of French peasants and described them as the living manifestation
of the hostility to the Revolution. Emigrés were both chastised for abandoning the fatherland
to avoid danger in times of political instability and condemned for joining forces with f oreign
tyrants” against the nation to restore a hated political regime. Revolutionaries thus passed a
series of laws against émigrés, depriving them of their state-funded pensions in 1790, legislating
that emigration was a crime in 1791, and eventually con…scating their property in 1792. In doing
7
France. Ministère des Finances. Eta ts Detaillés des Liquidations faites par la Co mmission d’Indem nité, a
l’époque du 31 décembre 1826 en Execut ion de la Loi du 27 avr il 1825, Paris, D e l’Imprimerie R oyale, 1827.
5
so, some of the revolutionaries were hoping to redistribute land and create a more egalitarian
society, but were disappointed not to see immediate consequences of their policies (e.g., Jones
(1988),Vivier (1998)).
The data collected by Greer (1951) on the émigrés during the Revolution paint a more
nuanced picture than the rhetoric of the revolutionaries, in terms of both the numbe r of émigrés
and their social compos ition. According to Greer (1951), the median département lost 0:31%
of its 1801 population (the rst year for which we have reliable population data). Panel A
of Figure 1 displays the intensity of émigrés as a share of the population throughout France,
showing substantial spatial variation. Panel A of Table 1 lists the départements with the highest
and lowest emigration rates. Moreover, a substantial fraction of émigrés (but not all of the m)
belonged to the local elites, as can be seen in Panel B of Table 1 for the 69 départements for which
such information is available. They were mainly aristocrats and clergymen, as well as wealthy
urban dwellers and rural landowners from the Third Estate whose property was con…scated and
sold (some even lost the property of the Church that they had acquired in the early stage of
the Revolution).
8
As Panel C of Table 1 shows, the shares of the di¤erent types of émigrés are
strongly correlated. Some of the commoners who left France were servants of aristocrats and
followed their employers abroad. Others were landless peasants or artisans either eeing for their
lives or searching for a better life (see Duc de Castries (1966)).
Revolutionary violence not only took several forms, but also its geographic and social
incidence was markedly di¤erent across French regions and social groups. The civil war was
mostly con…ned to the southeast and west of France, and was particularly intens e in the Vendée
département. The Reign of Terror, which entailed the use of the judicial system to assassinate
political opponents, was more intense in Paris, Lyon and Marseille (i.e., the three main French
cities), as well as in the west of France (Greer (1935), Gueni¤ey (2011)).
9
As such, unlike
the civil war and the judicial Terror, which were s patially concentrated, emigration was for
the contemporaries of the Revolution a spectacular consequence of revolutionary violence that,
at the time, seemed to ect all of France. Moreover, while France under the monarchy had
experienced civil war in the 16th and 17th centuries and while public executions were common
during the 18th century (e.g., Bée (1983), Bastien (2006)), emigration was a speci…c consequence
of the Revolution b ec ause it implied the precipitous decline of a previously conspicuous social
8
On averag e, nobles were richer than peasants, and anecdotal evidence sugges ts that they possessed more land
prior to 1789. Of course, there were exceptions, and the living conditions of some nobles, for instance, those in
Britt any (Nassiet (1993)), were no t really di¤erent from tho se of the peasants. This can explain why before 1789,
po litical antagonism also existed within each of the three orde rs, for example, between min or and gre at nob les
(Furet (1978)). It may also help to ratio nalize why, d uring the Revoluti on, some commoners were favorable to
a c onstitutional monarchy (e.g ., Jean-Joseph Mouni er) while some aris tocrats support ed the radical turn of the
Revolution (e.g., Louis-Michel Le Peletie r de Saint-Fargeau).
9
Greer (1935) repo rts that there were less than 10 executions in 27 départements during the Terror.
6
and political group.
10
In this respect, emigration also di¤ered from the violence stemming from
the civil war and the judicial Terror, which disproportionately ected peasants and workers.
11
2.2 The Intensi…cation of Emigration during the Second Revolution
During the summer of 1792, major political upheavals and widespread violence, starting with the
imprisonment of Louis XVI and his family in early August and culminating with the proclamation
of the republic a few weeks later, signi…ed the unraveling of the House of Bourbon and the
abolition of the monarchy. In Appendix A:2 we provide details on the unfolding of these events.
Many historical anecdotes describe how emigration accelerated during and immediately after the
summer of 1792 (e.g., Taine (1876-1893), Bou loiseau (1972), Tackett (2015)).
12
For instance,
reform-minded aristocrats who had played a political role in the rst years of the Revolution,
such as the Marquis de Lafayette and the Duc de la Rochefoucauld-Liancourt, left France in
August 1792. In fact, Tackett (2015) (p. 215) writes that in September 1792, conditions had
become so frightening that many wealthier families began eeing Paris (...). Others, however,
seem to have concluded that the countryside was even more dangerous than Paris.”An additional
historical piece of evidence pointing to the intensi…cation of the emigration in the fall of 1792 is
the reaction of the British government: it introduced the Aliens Act in the House of Lords on
December 19, 1792, in an attempt to regulate the uncontrolled in‡ux of French nationals, which
created signi…cant anxiety in governmental circles that feared the presence of revolutionary spies
and saboteurs.
Several local historians (listed in Marko¤ (1996)) explicitly link emigration to local episodes
of violence during the su mmer of 1792. For instance, in Var, a high-emigration département, local
violence took the form of several days of rioting in Toulon, between July 28, 1792, and September
10th, 1792, where local revolutionaries targeted aristocrats, military cers, and wheat traders
whom they considered hostile to the Revolution (Havard (1911-1913)). Members of these groups
ed France for Italy. In Ariège a band of peasants led by a local revolutionary began to ransack
and burn castles in late August 1792 (Arnaud (1904)). As a result, many aristocrats, bourgeois,
and refractory priests sou ght refuge in Spain.
10
Many Protestants left France after the revocation of the Edit de Na ntes in 1685 by King Louis XIV (Scoville
(1953)) . However, Fren ch Protestants did not hold the political clout of the aris tocra ts who emigrated, an d their
exodus did not coincide wit h a massive political and economi c tran sformation akin to that of the French Revolution.
11
Greer (1935) estimates (Table 8, pp. 165- 166) that peasants and workers ma de up a combi ned 59:25% of the
total 16; 594 death sentences during the Terror while the nobles were only 8:25%, clergymen 6:5%, members from
the upper middle class 14% and members from the lower middle class 10:5% (no status was given to the remaining
1:5% of individuals sentenced to death). Note that the seemingly low o¢ cial numbe r of victims obscures th e fact
that many more people were kil led without a trial during the Terror .
12
Arguably, some émigs had ed France befo re the summer of 1792. For instanc e, the Count of Artois, who
would become Ki ng Charles X (r. 1824-1830), left in 1789, and Jean-Joseph Mounier , one of the royalist leaders
of the Amis de la Constitution Mona rchique (Friends of the Mo narchic Constitution ), ed in 1790. A few also left
in the post-Thermidorian period in 1794-1795.
7
2.3 Emigration and Land Redistribution during the Revolution
The sale of the biens nationaux is con side red by some historians as the most important event
of the French Revolution” (Lecarpentier (1908), Bodinier and Teyssier (2000)). Their claim is
based on the fact that a signi…cant amount of land was seized and sold by the government under
the name of biens nationaux (national goods) during this period. This land belonged to the
Church, the émigrés, and the counterrevolutionaries. The property of the Church was rst seized
by the French revolutionaries to pay the debts of the French state on November 2, 1789. The
property of the émigrés and counterrevolutionaries was also con…scated for that purpose three
years later. It is not clear, however, whether the French state recovered much from those sales
due to its in‡ationary policies.
13
In addition, during the French Revolution, property rights were
granted on the villages’commons: some of the common land was sold to private individuals while
some of it was seized by the municipalities and, later on, leased to peasants (Vivier (1998)).
Land redistribution may have been consequential for the French départements for at least
two reasons. First, the amount of land which was seized and sold by the government during the
Revolution was signi…cant; Bodinier (1999) estimates that 10% of land changed hands. Second,
even though émigrés were invited to return to France in 1802 by Napoléon Bonaparte, he forbade
émigrés from reclaiming their landed property. The loss of their property was made permanent
in 1814 when it was rea¢ rmed by Louis XVIII (Louis XVI’s brother). Emigrés (and their
descendants) were to be compensated by the April 27, 1825, law, which came to be known as
the milliard des émigrés since these reparations amounted to nearly one billion French francs
(nearly 10% of the French GDP in 1825 (Maddison (2001))), but not all émigrés eventually
received comp ens ation for their losses. Overall, some of the émigrés were able to reconstitute
part of their landed estate, whereas others were only able to live a gentry life with modest means,
and some became destitute.
14
Nevertheless, there is no consensus as to who ultimately b ene …ted from the sale of the
biens nationaux. Schama (1989) suggests that the redistribution of land was not from the landed
elite to peasants, but rather a transfer of property within the landed classe s. The members of the
groups which were gaining economically before the Revolution and who managed to evade violence
13
For an overview of the successive laws pertaini ng to the sale of the biens nationaux, see Bodinier and Teyssier
(2000). For a speci…c analysis of the economic consequences of the sale of the Church property, see Finley, Franck,
and Johnson (20 17). On macroeco nomic policies during the French Re volution, see, for example, Sargent and Velde
(1995).
14
Aristocrats like the Marquis de Dr eux-B in Sarth e and Barral de Montfer rat in Isère emerged nancially
unscathed from the Revolutio n (Schama (1989 )). The Marquis de Lafayette seemed to have lost a large share of
his property and led a more modest life (Furet and Ozouf (1988)). Mme Lalanne, born Dudevant de Villeneuve,
solicited her admission to the poor house in Bordeaux (Gironde) that she had foun ded before the Revolution
(Boisnard (1992)). It must be noted that there is no evidence that the émi gs engaged in industrial and service
activities after their return; their ideological sta nce was certainly not conducive to such endeavors (Baldensperger
(1924)) .
8
by adopting a revolutionary stance (among them, many relatively wealthy urban bourgeois and
small farmers) emerged richer since they bought the landed properties of the Church and the
eeing landed gentry at a low price (see, e.g., Marion (1908), Cobb (1972), Sutherland (2003)).
Others argue that the sale of the biens nationaux was detrimental to the living conditions of
peasants during the 19th century because it created a small peasantry of su bsisten ce , thereby
consolidating the agrarian structure of France and delaying economic modernization (Loutchisky
(1897), Lefebvre (1924)). Finally, some contend that the redistribution of land was bene…cial to
French peasants: they became small-scale agrarian capitalists focused on market prod uc tion (Ado
(1987 [2012])). McPhee (1999), for example, provides anecdotal evidence on small landowners
who engaged in wine production in Herault.
Crucially, local monographs on the sale of the biens nationaux suggest that the eventual
extent of land redistribution and its bene…ciaries crucially depended on the extent of local em-
igration during the French Revolution. Th is is, in itself, partly to be expected since the biens
nationaux comprised the émigrés properties. Below, we provide examples revealing the inti-
mate relationship b etween the change in ownership structure, as a result of th e sale of the biens
nationaux in four départements, and the share of émigrés in the local population.
First, in Cher, which was the third lowest emigration département (0:11% of the popula-
tion), Marion (1908) documents that there was very little land parcelization and redistribution,
or if there was any, it bene…ted individuals who were already well . For instance, in Ivoy-le-Pré
(9886 ha, 2; 438 inhabitants), not a single plot of land owned by an émigré was sold, while a
large domain was transferred from the abbey of Laurois to a major secular landowner, the local
fermier-général (a p rivate tax collector u nde r the Old Regime). Similarly, in Menetou-Râtel
(2; 801 ha, 1; 195 inhabitants), only 25 properties were sold, and 13 out of the 17 bu yers were
already major or medium-size landowners.
Second, in Gironde, which was a close-to-median intensity emigration département (0:24%
of the population), Marion (1908) shows that the prope rties owned by the Church and the
émigrés were parcelized into several smaller land lots in many rural communes, thereby enabling
individuals who were previously landless to acquire some property. For instance, in Lu gon-et-
l’Île-du-Carnay (1094 ha, 947 inhabitants), some well-known merchants and notaries bought land,
but most of the buyers of biens nationaux were landless farmers and artisans (i.e., blacksmiths,
carpenters, coopers, masons, and shoemakers), who acquired small land plots.
Third, in Nord, an above-median intensity emigration département ( 0:35% of the popu-
lation), Lefebvre (1924) provides information for 15 villages in the district of Avesnes, which we
report in Table 2. The statistics reveal that large properties were parcelized, and there was a
substantial transfer of property from nobles to peasants and urban bourgeois. Moreover, part of
9
the land, often commons, whose property was in dispute was acquired by the state, that is, either
the central government or the local towns.
Finally, in Ille-et-Vilaine, a relatively high-emigration area (0:42% of the départements
population), many aristocrats lost a signi…cant part of their properties. The castle and the
domain of the Vaurouault family near Saint-Malo, for example, were sold as biens nationaux in
1793. The family bought back the castle at the beginning of the 19th century but pe rmanently
lost the domain to small peas ants (Boisnard (1992)). Another famous local aristocratic family
that lost some of its land was that of François-René de Chateaubriand, the romantic writer and
heir to one of the oldest baronies in Britanny. This unfortunate turn of events for François-René
de Chateaubriand’s family might explain why he was adamant later in his political career that
émigrés should b e compen sated (Chateaubriand (1847), pp. 517-533).
It is against this background that we interpret the share of émigrés in each département
as a p roxy f or the weakening of the local landed elites of the Old Regime and the extent of land
redistribution. Below, we establish the empirical validity of these claims and trace the economic
consequences of land parcelization over time.
3 Data and Empirical Methodology
3.1 Measures of Income, Workforce, and Human Capital
To capture the short- and medium-run ects of emigration on income per capita at the départe-
ment level prior to World War II, we use data on GDP per capita as reconstructed by Comb es ,
Lafourcade, Thisse, and Toutain (2011) and Caruana-Galizia (2013) for 1860, 1901 and 1930.
For the post-World War II period, data on income per capita at the département level are not
available before 1995, so we use data from the French National Institute of Statistics (INSEE,
Institut National de la Statistique et des Etudes Economiques) for 1995, 2000, and 2010. We also
construct the value added per worker in the agricultural, industrial, and service sec tors combining
the data of Combes, Lafourcade, Thisse, and Toutain (2011), who assess the value added in each
of thes e three sectors in 1860, 1930, 1982, and 1990, with the occupational data from the gov-
ernmental surveys carried out from the 19th century onward (Statistique Générale de la France
and INSEE). The descriptive statistics in Table D.2 indicate that the shares of the workforce in
the industrial and service sectors grew, respectively, from 21:6% and 15:3% in 1860 to 30:1% and
24:8% in 1930, indicating that slightly less than h alf of the working French population was still
engaged in agriculture before WWII. However, by 1990, the share of the agricultural workforce
had declined considerably, with the industrial and service sectors employing 30:7% and 60:0% of
the workforce, respectively.
We also explore the ect of emigration during the French Revolution on the evolution of
10
human capital from the 19th century until today. For the period before World War II, we take
advantage of the data on the literacy of French army conscripts (France - Ministère de la Guerre
(1839-1937)).
15
The data enable us to compute the average share of illiterate conscripts, that is,
those who could neither read nor write, by decade between the 1840s and 1930s. Our statistics
in Table D.3 show the overall relatively high levels of literacy in France. Speci…cally, 26:7% of
French army conscripts in the 1840s, 16:0% in the 1870s, and 5:1% in the 1930s could neither read
nor write. Our post Word War II measures of human capital rely on the successive population
censuses carried out in 1968, 1975, 1982, 1990, 1999, and 2010. They allow us to compu te the
ow of men between the ages of 16 and 24 in each département who completed high school or
had a college degree or both.
3.2 Emigrés and Temp erature Shocks in the Summer of 1792
The observed relationship between em igration and regional development may re‡ect omitted vari-
ables which could explain both emigration and subsequent economic performance. For instance,
if emigration was proportional to the pool of potential”émigrés, then high-emigration départe-
ments would be those with initially many nobles and many wealthy landowners. In other words,
since we do not have département-level data before and after the Revolution on the relative size
of each order (i.e., the nobility, the clergy, and the Third Estate) observed emigration rates may
be mechanically linked to the initial regional stock of the old elite and the extent of land con-
centration prior to 1789, thereby biasing ou r estimates. Moreover, despite the thorough orts
to accurately reconstruct the numbers, (Greer (1951), p.17) acknowledges th at his statistics,
cannot pretend to absolute exactitude. They include an irregular margin of error. In a few places
it may infringe as much as fty per cent (e.g., in Var), in others it narrows to insigni…cance
(e.g., in Basses-Alpes).”
16
Another limitation of Greer (1951)’s data is that they do not provide
a yearly breakdown on the timing of emigration for each département but only for the 1789-1799
period as a whole.
To overcome these important measurement issues, we leverage the spatial variation in the
temperature shocks in the summer of 1792 as a source of variation for the share of émigrés in the
population of each département. Our identi…cation strategy is motivated by a strand of literature
documenting the ect of climate on human activity and the outbreak of violence. The logic
is that abnormal weather conditions cause a tem porary decline in agricultural output, that is,
a transitory negative income shock for farming-based economies. Such a shock decreases the
15
These da ta are not subject to selection bias because every Frenchm an had to report for military service.
However, changes in consc ription rules meant that not every man eventually s erved during the 19th century
(Crépin (2009)).
16
Hi gonnet (1981) suggests, for example, that there were about 25; 000 noble émigrés inste ad of 16; 431, as
estimated by Gr eer (1951).
11
opportunity cost of violence which in our historical context can be meas ured by the intensity
of emigration rates across départements. For instance, in Orne in the west of France, a high-
emigration and high-temperature shock département in the summer of 1792, the villagers of Rai
and Corsei ransacked the Castle of Rai on Se ptemb er 23, 1792, demanding that the lord of the
manor abandon his feudal rights.
17
It is not clear when the emigration ows, triggered by the events of the summer of 1792,
stopped. It is possible that emigration in some départements took place over several months
because violence continued after the summer of 1792. In this respect, two groups of regions stand
out. First, the départements of Deux-Sèvres, Loire-Inférieure, Maine-et-Loire, Morbihan, and
Vendée were the locus of the civil war in the west of France (e.g., Tilly (1964), Martin (1987)),
and second, the départements of Bouches-du-Rhône, Calvados, Gironde, and Var participated in
the Federalist Revolt in 1793 (see, e.g., Johnson (1986)). The common characteristic of these
territories was that they experienced high-temperature shocks in the summer of 1792 which
triggered a period of prolonged emigration and unrest.
In what follows, we explore the ects of the di¤erential pattern of emigration during the
Revolution, which we show to be partly shaped by transitory local weather shocks in the summer
of 1792, on the long-term process of development across French départements. Our conjecture is
that emigration is likely to have had both medium- and long-run repercussions via the channels
of land redistribution and the curtailing of the upper tail of the local wealth distribution. In
this respect, it stands to reason that any direct economic impact of the summer shocks of 1792
beyond their ect on emigration rates is unlikely to be quantitatively relevant several decades
after the event.
Note. In Appendix B, we er two complementary pieces of evidence regarding the impact
of temperature shocks on economic conditions and lo c al violence. First, in Appendix B:1 we show
that larger temperature shocks translate into spikes in local wheat prices using data collected by
Labrousse, Romano, and Dreyfus (1970) for the 1797-1800 period which covers the latter part
of the Revolution (see Figure A.3 and columns (1)-(5) of Table D.5). Second, in Appendix B:2
we use the dataset on peasant revolts assembled by Marko¤ (1996) to quantitatively establish
that abnormal tem peratures in the summer of 1792 are systematically related to the incidence
of p eas ant revolts during the Second Revolution”(see Figure A.1 and columns (6)-(7) of Table
D.5).
17
The lord of the m an or was Louis-bastien Des douits du Ray, a commoner who had been ennobled thanks to
the fortune he had m ad e when working in the Compagnie des Indes (du Mote y (1893), pp. 108-109). His children
emig rated, and years later, in 1826, he and his wife were compensated as ascendants of émigrés under the April 27,
1825, law for the property losses incur red during the French Revolutio n (France - Ministère des Finances. Etats
ta illés des Liquidations f aites par la Commis sion dIndemnité, à l’époque du 1er avril 1826 en Ecution de la
Loi du 27 avril 1825, Paris, De l’Imprim erie Royale, 1826. Vo l. 2, pp.2-3).
12
3.3 Temperature Shocks Construction
Our tempe rature data come from the Europ e an Seasonal Temperature and Precipitation Re-
construction Project, which was developed by paleoclimatologists at the University of Berne
(Luterbacher, Dietrich, Xoplaki, Grosjean, and Wanner (2004), Luterbacher, Dietrich, Xoplaki,
Grosjean, and Wanner (2006), Pauling, Luterbacher, Casty, and Wanner (2006)). These are
season-speci…c reconstructions for the 1500-1900 period, at a resolution of 0:5 by 0:5 decimal
degrees. These data are assembled using a multiplicity of indirect proxies such as tree rings,
ice cores, corals, ocean and lake sediments, as well as historical doc ume ntary records. As such,
measurement error may be nontrivial. Moreover, climatic records are interpolated over relatively
large areas, resulting in two cells per département on average.
18
According to the authors, the
quality and breadth of the underlying sources improve over time, particularly from the end of
the 18th century onward.
We follow Hidalgo, Naidu, Nichter, and Richardson (2010) and Franck (2016) and employ
two alternative measures of temperature shocks for the summer of 1792. First, we us e the squared
deviation of temperature:
Z
d;t;s
=
x
d;t;s
x
d;s
d;s
2
;
where the temperature x
d;t;s
in département d in year t of season s is standardized by the mean
x
d;s
and the standard deviation
d;s
of temperature in each département d in season s, where
both the mean and standard deviation are computed over a baseline period. The baseline p eriod
which we use to compute x
d;s
and
d;s
comprises all the s umme r temperatures in the 25 years
before 1792 (i.e., from 1767 until 1791). As we discuss below, we consider several robustne ss
checks to this baseline speci…cation.
Second, we de…ne the absolute deviation of temperature as:
Z
d;t;s
=
x
d;t;s
x
d;s
d;s
;
Panel B of Figure 1 maps the spatial distribution of the mean temperature in the summer
of 1792, while Panel C of Figure 1 portrays the squared deviation of temperature. In Panel D
we present these temperature shocks after partialing out the time-invariant geographic controls
described below. The observed spatial variation in temperature shocks of Panel D is our source
of identi…cation.
18
partements were designed in 1790 to be o f relatively small size so that it would take at most one day of
horse travel to reach the département s administr ative center from any location in the département. On aver age,
the d épartement s area is 6; 000 km
2
, which is approxi mate ly the size of the US state of Delaware.
13
It is important to note that the summer of 1792 was comparable to the other summers
during the Revolution. The descriptive statistics in Table D.4 indeed show that the summer of
1792 is at the median of the summer temperature distribution for the 1788-1799 period, with an
average temperature of 17:97, standard deviation 1:36, and a minimum (maximum) temperature
of 13:69 (21:82). The temperature in the summer of 1792 was therefore less unusual than the
summers of 1788 and 1789 which led to the outbreak of the Revolution. In fact, the descriptive
statistics in Table D.4 show that the average temperature shock in the summer of 1792 was milder
than any other summer temperature shock during the 1788-1799 period.
3.4 Confounding Characteristics of Each Département
3.4.1 Geographic Characteristics
In the e mpirical analysis below, we control for the départements area, land suitability for agri-
culture, elevation, longitude and latitude. These geographic characteristics may in‡uence both a
region’s emigration rate as well as its agricultural comparative advantage and hence the pace of
industrialization and, ultimately, economic growth. Controlling for longitude and latitude also
enables us to account for the location of industries before (and after) the Revolution that were
mostly situated in the east and north of France. Moreover, given the importance of temperature
shocks in 1792 for our identi…cation strategy (see below), we control for the average temperature
in the summer of 1792. In addition, we take into account the distance from each départements
main administrative center (chef-lieu) to the coast, the border, and the three largest urban cen-
ters (before the French Revolution and to this day), Paris, Lyon, and Marseille. These variables
capture the potential confounding ects of the geographic location of the départements, which
may have ected emigration intensity and local development via the proximity to trade routes.
3.4.2 Prerevolutionary Characteristics
Di¤erences in loc al pre-1789 development outcomes may have jointly ected emigration during
the Revolution and the subsequent evolution of income per capita. To account for these poten-
tially confounding factors, we add the following proxies. First, to capture prerevolutionary levels
of human capital, particularly the upper end of the distribution, we use an indicator for the
presence of a university in 1700 in the département (Bosker, Buringh, and van Zanden (2013)).
Second, we compute the share of the population that subscribed to the Quarto edition of the En-
cyclopédie in the mid -18th century (Darnton (1973), Squicciarini and Voigtländer (2015)) which
also captures the di¤usion of the ideas of the Enlightenment within France. Third, we construct
the number of mechanical mills in 1789 used in textile production (Bonin and Langlois (1997)).
This variable not only accounts for early industrialization but also for prerevolutionary agita-
14
tion as a substantial number of riots in France in 1788 and 1789 occurred in textile-producing
regions that su¤ered from the increased competition from English manufacturers after the sig-
nature of the Eden Treaty in 1786 (which lowered tari¤s between England and France (Mathiez
(1922-1924))).
19
Finally, we add a dummy for the départements which Vivier (1998) singles out
as having few commons just before the outbreak of the Revolution and hence more established
private prop erty rights over land.
3.5 Empirical Model
The ect of emigration during the French Revolution on economic development is estimated
using 2SLS. The second stage provides a cross-sectional estimate of the relationship between the
share of émigrés in the population in each département du ring the Revolution and measures of
GDP p er capita, human capital, and additional economic outcomes at di¤erent points in time:
Y
d;t
= + E
d
+ X
0
d
:! + "
d;t
;
where Y
d;t
represents some proxy of economic performance in département d in year t, E
d
is the
log of the share of émigrés in the population of département d, X
0
d
is a vector of geographical and
prerevolutionary characteristics of département d, and "
d;t
is an i.i.d. error term for département
d in year t.
In the rst stage, E
d
; the log of the share of émigrés in the population of département d
during the French Revolution is instrumented by Z
d;1792
, the squared (or absolute) deviation of
temperature in the summer of 1792:
E
d
=
0
+
1
Z
d;1792
+ X
0
d
:! +
d
;
where X
0
d
is a vector of geographical and prerevolutionary traits of département d described
above.
4 Results
4.1 First Stage: Temperature Shocks in the Summer of 1792 and Emigration
The rst-stage results are reported in Table 3 where the instrument is the squared (absolute) stan-
dardized deviation from average temperature in the summer of 1792 in columns (1)-(3) (columns
(4)-(6)). In all speci…cations and irrespective of the inclusion of geographic and historical con-
trols, the estimates reveal that the squared and absolute temperature deviations in the summer
19
On the Eden Treaty, see, for example, Henderson (1957), and on the consequences of t he disruption to interna-
tional trade caused by the revolutionary and Napoleonic Wars, see, for example, Heckscher (1922), Crouzet (1964)
and Juhász (2015).
15
of 1792 are positively and signi…cantly correlated at the 1% level with variations in the share of
émigrés across French départements. Th is ect is also quantitatively large. In column (3) of
Table 3, the beta co cient equals to 0:549. Put di¤erently, a one-standard-deviation increase
in the squared deviation from temperature in the summer of 1792 (0:067) increases the share of
émigrés in the population by 0:42% (relative to a sample mean of 0:47% and a standard deviation
of 0:64%). Moreover, the F-statistic of the rst stage is equal to 16:88 in the speci…cation where
the instrumental variable is the squared deviation of temperature in 1792 (column (3)) and 11:32
in the speci…cation where the instrumental variable is the absolute deviation of temperature in
1792 (column (6)), su ggesting that these instruments are not weak. Figure 2 graphs the rst-
stage relationship between the squared deviation from average temperature in the summer of 1792
and the share of émigrés, conditional on geographic characteristics (Panel A) and conditional on
geographic and pre-1789 historical characteristics (Panel B).
Note. In Appendix B:3, we provide a series of robustness checks on the uncovered link
between temperature shocks in the summe r of 1792 and variation in the share of émigrés. These
robustness checks have a dual goal. The rst is to highlight that consistent with the historical
narrative, the temperature shock of the summer of 1792 is the only signi…cant determinant of
emigration among all the temp erature shocks during the revolutionary period. Speci…cally, we
show that emigration rates are not explained by (i) temperature shocks in the other three seasons
of 1792 (Table D.6); (ii) summer temperature deviations between 1788 and 1800 (Table D.7); or
(iii) rainfall shocks in the summer of 1792 (Table D.8). We also show that (iv) Conley-corrected
standard errors at various distance thresholds provide similar rst-stage results (Table D.9); (v)
and alternative time windows to standardize the temperature shocks (Table D.10) do not change
the patterns found.
Second, in an attempt to strengthen our identi…cation assumption, namely that the weather
shock in the su mmer of 1792 is uncorrelated with preexisting social and economic traits, we
gathered salient pre-revolutionary covariates at the département level and tested whe ther these
features predict the 1792 temperature deviation. S uch c ovariates include (i) episo d es of violence
immediately before (and after) the Revolution; (ii) complaints of the French population in 1789
as expressed in the cahiers de doléances; (iii) human capital before the Revolution proxied by
the share of brides and grooms that were able to sign their wedding contracts; (iv) the share of
the clergy that was hostile to the Revolution, and (v) the number of famous aristocratic families.
All in all, the results in Table D.11 are reassuring. None of these potentially important variables
correlates with our instrument, thus suggesting that it is a plausible source of identi…cation for
the impact of emigration on regional economic performance in the short and longue durée.
16
4.2 The ect of the Emigrés on the Economy in the Medium and Long Run
In this subsection, we explore the impact of emigration during the Revolution on several economic
outcomes over time, namely income per capita, sectoral labor productivity, and the composition
of the workforce.
4.2.1 Emigrés and the Evolution of Income per Capita
The relationship between emigration and income per capita up to World War II is presented in
Table 4, where the instrument is the squared deviation from standardized temperature in the
summer of 1792. Table D.12 in Append ix D replicates Table 4 using the absolute deviation
from standardized temperature in the su mmer of 1792: As shown in columns (1), (5), and (9) in
Panel A of Table 4, the unconditional OLS relationship between emigration and GDP per capita
is negative in 1860 and 1901, and turns positive in 1930 but is insigni…cant. The relationship
between emigration and income per capita in 1860 strengthens and becomes signi…cant when
we account for geographical factors in column (2). The 2SLS estimates in columns (3)-(4), (7)-
(8), and (11)-(12) in Panel A of Table 4 reveal that there is a negative and signi…cant ect
of emigration on income per c apita in 1860 and 1901 as well as a negative but insigni…cant
ect in 1930, whether we only account for geographic controls or include both geographic and
prehistorical controls. A half-percentage-point increase in the share of émigrés in a département
decreases GDP per capita by 12:8% in 1860 and 18:8% in 1901.
20
In both Tables 4 and D.12, the
co cient estimates associated with the share of émigrés in the 2SLS regress ions are signi…cantly
larger than the corresponding OLS ones. Besides measurement error in the share of émigrés
resulting in attenuation bias in the OLS co cients, an additional and p erhap s more pertinent
explanation for the downward bias of the OLS co cient arises from the fact that the unobserved
initial presence of wealthy landowners and priests in the p op ulation of a given département (the
stock) and their measured share in the départements population (the ow) are mechanically
linked.
An alternative way to assess the negative but eventually vanishing impact of emigration
on local economic development during the 19th and early 20th centuries can be seen in Figure
D.4 where we take advantage of the data from Bonneuil (1997) on fertility and infant mortality
between 1811 and 1901. The fertility rate is computed as the Coale fertility index (Coale (1969))
for each département, while the infant mortality rate is computed as the share of children who
20
Few of our geographic and historical contr ols a re signicant in the 2SLS regressions reported in columns
(8) and (12). Longitude is positively correlated with in come per capita in 1860 and 1901, probably reecting
the fact that par tements in the east o f France were more industrialized. A lack of c ommons in the 1780s
is also positi vely correlated with income per capita, which could be expected since commons were detrimental to
ag ricultur al produ cti vity. Finally, distance to the coast has a negative impact on income, as landlocked départeme nts
could not prot from maritime trade.
17
died before their rst birthday. In Figure D.4 we report the coe¢ cients associated with the share
of émigrés in 2SLS regressions (available upon request) wh ere the dependent variable is the Coale
fertility index (Panel A) and infant mortality (Panel B). A high share of émigrés has a positive
and signi…cant ect on fertility an d infant mortality until the 1880s, and no signi…cant impact
afterward.
The relationship between emigration and income per capita in the long run is presented in
Panel B of Table 4. As shown in columns (1), (5) and (9) unconditionally, emigration during the
Revolution has an insigni…cant positive association with income per capita across départements in
1995, 2000, and 2010. This relationship becomes signi…cantly positive once geographical features
are accounted for in columns (2), (6), and (10). Finally, the 2SLS estimates in columns (3)-(4),
(7)-(8), and (11)-(12) in Panel B of Table 4 suggest that emigration had a positive ect in the
long run. A half-percentage-point increase in emigration increases GDP per capita in 1995 by
8:7%, in 2000 by 9:8%, and in 2010 by 8:8%.
21
Similar results are reported in Table D.12 in
Appendix D.
Our 2SLS estimates in Tables 4 and D.12 indicate that there was a reversal of the ect of
emigration on income per capita: départements with more emigration were poorer until World
War I but became richer by the turn of the 21st century. We illustrate this reversal by plotting
in Figure 3 the co cients associated with the share of émigrés in the 2SLS regressions reported
in columns (4), (8), and (12) of Panels A and B in Tables 4 and D.12.
Robustness checks. This reversal in the impact of emigration on economic performance
is driven neither by a speci…c group of départements nor by outlier départements with too few”
or too many”émigrés. In Figure 4, we plot the co cients from 2SLS regressions on GDP per
capita in 1860 and 2010 where we remove one nuts 1”region at a time.
22
In Figure 5, we plot
the coe¢ cients from 2SLS regressions on GDP per capita in 1860 and 2010, where we remove the
top and bottom 1%, 5%, 10% and 20% départements in the distribution of the share of émigrés.
Under all these alternative permutations, the co cient associated with the share of émigrés in
the 2SLS regressions remains consistently signi…cant: negative in 1860 and positive in 2010.
This pattern is also evident in the reduced-form estimates reported in Table D.7 in Appen-
dix D. Panels A and B of Figure 6 graph the reduced-form relationships between the temperature
shock in the summer of 1792 and GDP per capita in 1860 and 2010, respectively. Moreover, the
reduced-form regressions in Table D.7 in Appendix D show that no temperature shock in the
21
In the 2SLS regre ssion s, three covariate s have a systematic signi…cant ect on GDP per capita in 1995, 2000,
and 2010. Speci…cally, the di stance of each département from Paris and Lyon is negatively correlated with income,
indicating the importance of these two major urb an centers on spatial d evelopment. Furth ermore we nd that the
département s area is positively correla ted with income, suggesting the presence o f scale ects.
22
The nomenc lature o f territorial units for statistics (or “nuts”) i s a standard fo r referencing administrative
divisions within European Union c ountries. Here we use the rst level of nuts” for France.
18
summers between 1788 and 1800, other than that of 1792, can explain this reversal. We also
show that the sign and statistical s igni…cance in the reduced-form relationship between tempera-
ture shocks in 1792 and GDP per capita in 1860 and 2010 is robust to using baselines other than
the 25 years preceding 1792, that is, using the 50 years before 1792 (1743-1791) or the 1751-1800,
1751-1775, and 1776-1800 periods in Table D.10 in Appendix D.
Finally, in Table D.13, we examine the impact of the social status of émigrés on GDP
per capita in 1860 and 2010 by distinguishing between rich émigrés (aristocrats, priests, and
upper middle class) and poor émigrés (lower middle class, workers, and peasants). Even though
statistics on these social groups of émigrés are only available for 69 out of 86 départements, the
2SLS regression results in Table D.13 are qualitatively similar to those in Table 4 insofar as the
shares of rich and poor émigrés have a negative and signi…cant ect on GDP per capita in 1860
and a positive and signi…cant impact on GDP per capita in 2010.
4.2.2 Emigrés, Labor Productivity, and the Workforce
This subsection explores the ect of emigration on labor productivity in the di¤erent sectors of
the economy. In Panel A of Table 5, we examine the impact of emigration on the value added
per worker in the agricultural, industrial, and service sectors in 1860, 1930, 1982, and 1990,
respectively. The 2SLS regressions in colum ns (1)-(3) show that emigration had a signi…cantly
negative impact on productivity in all three sectors in 1860. The estimates in columns (4)-(6)
reveal that there was still a negative ect of emigration on agricultural productivity in 1930.
However, in columns (7)-(12), the ect of the share of émigrés on pro du ctivity in each sector in
1982 and 1990 is pos itive and signi…cant.
The negative ect of the share of émigrés on agricultural productivity in the mid-19th
century can be partially accounted for by the limited mechanization in agriculture in 1862 in high-
emigration départements. Speci…cally, in Table 6 we nd th at, out of the 15 di¤erent categories of
agricultural instruments per worker in the agricultural sector, emigration is negatively correlated
with 13 of these inputs, and this ect is signi…cant for the quantity of fertilizer and the number
of scari…ers, grubbers, searchers, seeders, and tedders. It is also signi…cantly and negatively
correlated with the rst principal component of all these agricultural tools per worker in the
agricultural sector. These results are in line with the view that French agriculture remained
relatively backward as a result of the French Revolution.
23
In Panel B of Table 5, we examine the impact of emigration on the share of the workforce
employed in the agricultural, industrial, and service sectors. The 2SLS regressions in columns
23
In regressions available upon request, which are moti vated by the study of Rosenthal (1988) on irrigation in
the aft erma th of the Revolution, we analyze the impact of emigration during the Revolution on the area drained
in each department as wel l as the number of pipe factorie s in each département in 1856 using the information in
Barral (18 58). We nd that emigration had an insig ni…cant impact on bo th variables.
19
(1)-(3) show that emigration had a positive but insigni…cant impact on the share of the workforce
in the agricultural sector in 1860, a positive and signi…cant ect at the 10% level on the share
of the workforce in the service sector, but a negative and signi…cant ect at the 1% level on the
share of the workforce in the industrial sector. This last result suggests that emigration during
the French Revolution delayed the structural transformation of France toward the industrial era,
in line with the analysis of Cobban (1962). Moreover, the regressions in columns (4)-(6) show
that in 1930, emigration still had an insigni…cant ect on the share of the workforce in the
agricultural sector, a negative and signi…cant ect at the 10% level on the share of the workforce
in the industrial sector, and a positive and signi…cant ect at the 5% level on the share of the
workforce in the service sector. Finally, the regressions in columns (7)-(9) show that in 2010,
emigration had a negative and signi…cant ect at the 1% level on the share of the workforce in
the agricultural sector as well as a positive and signi…cant ect on the sh ares of the workforce
in the industrial s ector at the 5% level and in the service sector at the 1% level.
All in all, the evidence in Tables 5 and 6 sheds some light on the sources of the nega-
tive impact of emigration on incomes during the 19th century shown in Table 4. It suggests
that emigration during the French Revolution disp roportionately and inverse ly ected agricul-
tural productivity up until World War II and slowe d down the structural transformation toward
industry during the 19th century. Nevertheless, since the second half of the 20th century, high-
emigration départements have been hosting a more productive workforce in the industrial and
service sectors.
24
5 Mechanisms
In this section we explore some potential channels which may account for the ne gative ect of
emigration during the Revolution on the standards of living in the 19th century and its positive
ect toward the end of the 20th century. First, we investigate how the absence of émigrés seems
to have had an impact on the size and the composition of the local elites during the 19th century.
Second, we analyze the impact of émigrés on the landownership structure. Finally, we examine
their ect on the evolution of human capital across départements over time.
5.1 Emigration during the Revolution and the Economic Elites of the 19th
Century
Here we investigate how emigration during the Revolution in‡uenced the size and composition of
local elites during the 19th century. The 2SLS estimates in Table 7 focus on electors in the 1839
24
In Tab le D.14, we examine the impact of emigration during the Revolution on t he population in each départe-
ment (Panel A) as well as in the chef -lieu (i.e., administrati ve ce nter) of each partement (Panel B). We nd that
emig ration during the Re volution has no impact on population density until World War II.
20
elections under the regime of the July monarchy (1830-1848). At that time, the voting franchise
was restricted to men above the age of 25 who could pay 200 francs worth of direct annual taxes.
This was a signi…cant amount cons idering that th e average daily wage of bakers in Paris in 1840
was equal to four francs (Chevallier (1887), p.46).
The 2SLS estimates in column (1) of Table 7 show that émigrés had a negative ect
on the share of electors in the popu lation in 1839. The presence of a smaller economic elite in
high-émigrés areas suggests that the local elites were severely weakened by emigration during
the Revolution, leaving these départements with fewer wealthy individuals who could potentially
fund the costly investments of industrialization. This nding is in line with the evidence in Table
5, that départements with a large share of émigrés were characterized by both lower productivity
and lower employment in the industrial sector.
25
Moreover, the estimates in Table 7 suggest that emigration had a negative ect on the
share of landowners among the electors (column (2)), a positive but insigni…cant ect on the
share of businessmen and professionals (i.e., doctors and lawyers) (columns (3)-(4)), as well as a
positive and signi…cant ect on the share of civil servants (column (5)). The nding in column
(2) highlights the relative paucity of su¢ ciently wealthy landowners that may explain the lower
agricultural productivity in 1860 in high-emigration départements. We come back to this issue
in the next section where we d iscu ss in detail how the composition of agricultural landholdings
shaped local development.
The estimate in column (5) of Table 7 shows that in 1839, electors in high-emigration
départements were disproportionately drawn from the pool of civil servants. At rst, this pat-
tern may seem puzzling, but it is in line with the analysis of Tocqueville (1856) on how the
French Revolution contributed to the growth of the French adminis tration and the central state.
The increased presence of civil servants in high-emigration départements is corroborated by the
estimates in Table D.16, where we show that emigration had a positive and signi…cant ect
on the workforce share of civil servants in 1851 and 1866 as well as a positive but insigni…cant
one in 1881. All in all, the evidence suggests that there were relatively more civil servants, and
presumably, a more powerful administrative machine, in the départements where the Revolution
had been more intense, as proxied by the share of émigrés in the population.
25
In Tab le D.15, we examine the impact of emigrati on on local nancial development. We proxy the latter by
the total value of loans (in Fre nch francs) granted by local savings banks and by the number of contr acts sealed
by notaries in each département, keeping in mind that notaries had, by the second half of the 19th century, lost
their central role as nancial intermediari es which they ha d held prior to the Revolution (Ho¤man, Postel-Vinay,
and Rosenth al ( 2000)). We nd that emigration is negatively correlated with both measures during the 19th
century ( the e¤ect is, however, only signicant on the number of co ntracts sealed by notaries in 1861). Overall,
the results sugge st t hat the negative ect of émigrés on GDP per capita only weakly stemmed from nancial
underdevelopment.
21
5.2 Emigration during the Revolution and the Composition of Agricultural
Holdings
We have already established that in départements with a higher share of émigrés, labor agricul-
tural productivity was signi…cantly lower and fewer rich landowners voted in the elections held
in 1839. In this section, we further examine the impact of emigration on the size of agricultural
landholdings.
In the agricultural census of 1862, landholdings are categorized in brackets according to
their size. The largest landholdings are those in the category above 40 hectares. Given the
historical account and the evidence on the composition of the elites, one would expect to nd
that high-emigration départements have a dearth of large holdings. This is shown to be the
case in column (1) in Panel A of Table 8 where the dependent variable is the share of farms
above 40 hectares: a one-percentage-point increase in the share of émigrés in the population
decreases the share of farms above 40 hectares in 1862 by 1:54%. It is instructive to link this
nding with the work of David (1975) (pp.221-231) on the adoption of the mechanical reaper
for harvesting wheat in 1854-1857 in the United States. He nds that the mechanical reaper
was only economically viable for farms larger than roughly 20 hectares. In 1862 only 13% of
farms were above 20 hectares in the median French département, while 52:9% and 58:5% of farms
were above that threshold in the United States in 1860 and England in 1851 (Grigg (1992)),
respectively. Moreover, as we show in column (2), French départements that experienced a
larger exodus during the Revolution had systematically fewer farms above this scale-e¢ cient size.
Namely, we nd that a one-percentage-point inc rease in the share of émigrés in the population
decreased the share of farms above 20 hectares in 1862 by 0:87%. This absence of su¢ ciently
large landholdings echoes the ndings in Table 6 regarding th e delayed mechanization of French
agriculture in high-emigration départements.
In columns (3)-(5) in Panel A of Table 8, our de pendent variables are the ratio of the number
of farms of 40 hectares and above to the number of farms below 10 hectares in 1862 and the ratio
of the number of farms of 50 hectares and above to the number of farms below 10 hectares in 1929
and 2000. These variables are meant to capture the relative abundance of large- to small-sized
farms within a département. Over the last 150 years, regions in France where emigration was
more intense during the 1789 Revolution consistently feature an agricultural landscape dominated
by small- to medium-sized farmers and a scarcity of large ones.
26
The demise of large landed
elites and the creation of a small peasantry mainly working for subsistence, at least until World
War II, was part of the legacy of the émigrés ight during the French Revolution. Panels C
and D of Figure 6 plot th e residuals of the reduced-form regressions between the summer of 1792
26
Additional results available upon request show that the share of émigrés had a positive but insignicant ect
on the total number of farms and to tal number of farms per inhabitant in 1862.
22
temperature shock and the ratio of farms above 40 hectares to farms below 10 hectares in 1862
and between the summer of 1792 temperature shock and the share of farms above 20 hectares in
1862.
It is interesting to compare the results in Panel A of Table 8 to those of Finley, Franck,
and Johnson (2017), who nd that the auctions of Church land during the Revolution are pos-
itively correlated with land concentration during the mid-19th century (and hence, with higher
investments in agriculture). Their rationale is that the auctions of Church property, which took
place in the early stages of the Revolution before the summer of 1792, mainly entailed a transfer
of land from the Church to members of the wealthier sections of the local society. In our context,
the extent to which the local elite might eventually have been able to bene…t from the Church
property would depend on the extent of emigration during the Revolution. In other words, if
our conjecture is right, one would expect to nd that the negative impact of emigration on land
concentration to be magni…ed in areas where more Church land was auctioned. This is what we
nd in Panel B of Table 8, where we run reduced-form regressions on the 67 départements for
which we have information on the share of the Church property sold during the Revolution (Bo-
dinier and Teyssier (2000)). Speci…cally, we control for the latter and add the interaction term
between the share of Church land sold in each département and the temperature s hocks in the
summer of 1792. In all the regressions, we nd, in line with Finley, Franck, and Johnson (2017),
that the share of the Church property sold in each département is positively correlated with the
presence of large estates, and more importantly for our analysis, that the interaction term is
negative and highly signi…cant. The direct ect of temperature shocks also remains precisely
estimated, suggesting that emigration did lead to a decline in the share of large landowners even
in the absence of Church land redistribution. Its impact, ne vertheless, was signi…cantly stronger
precisely where more Church land was sold.
One may naturally wonder why market forces did not correct”this ine¢ cient size of small
landholdings over time. In other words, why did this lopsided ownership structure in agriculture
survive when one would expect consolidation to take place? Although a thorough exploration
of this subject would take us beyond the con…nes of the current study, we venture a tentative
explanation below.
First of all, it must be noted that there was no deliberate, cial policy designed speci…cally
to perpetuate the fragmentation of landownership status quo during the 19th century (Agulhon,
Désert, and Specklin (1976)). Nevertheless, the existence of the octrois might help to explain why
the tendency toward consolidation might have been less pronounced. The octrois were the local
taxes levied on almost all goods entering towns (e.g., meat, wine, fruits, vegetables, coal, etc.)
and, de facto, functioned as internal trade barriers within France (before and after 1789, as they
23
were only nally abolished in 1943). These octrois favored small local farmers whos e production
would be exempt from paying them. Throughout the 19th century, the central government
progressively reined in the ability of towns to levy octrois, and on December 29, 1897, the French
Parliament passed a law which came into ect on January 1, 1901, dictating a substantial
decrease in octrois rates. This law, which was the outcome of the lobbying from progressives”
who sought to improve citizens’ health by promoting the consumption of wine as opposed to
liquor, b e ne…ted large wine producers in the south, who were able to produce cheap wine in large
quantities. The law thus crowded out small wine producers who successfully lobbied for costly
anti-competitive legislation which was adopted in 1905 to reduce fraud and adulteration in the
wine m arket and which, de facto, protected small producers of local wine (Franck, Johnson, and
Nye (2014)). This example suggests that local demand for barriers to entry would be stronger in
regions dominated by small landowners since competition from large farmers would be damaging
to their revenues. In fact this is what we nd in Table D.17: départements with a larger share
of émigrés had in 1875 more French towns (“communes”) which were protected by octrois taxes,
and the magnitude of these taxes for various pro du cts were also likely to be signi…cantly higher.
Another potential explanation for the negative impact of emigration on agricultural pro-
ductivity may stem from the positive ect of emigration on the share of commons in e ach
département in 1863, as can be seen in column (6) in Panel A of Table 8. A one-percentage-point
increase in the share of émigrés in the population increases by 1:72% the share of commons in
1863 . As discu sse d by Vivier (1998), there is ample anecdotal evidence that the central state
and the local governments seized the commons during the Revolution in places where there were
more émigrés. In turn, the local governments leased those lands to farmers for a limited number
of years. Such leases in agriculture may have had a negative e ct on agricultural productivity
by limiting investments in machinery and promoting intensive production methods which would
be damaging for land productivity in the long run.
27
The evidence in this section provides a possible f oray into u nd erstand ing why local in comes
were depressed during the 19th century in regions that émigrés left in large numbers. Can the
same economic forces, re‡ecte d in the distribution of agricultural landholdings, help to explain
the takeo¤ of these initially lagging regions? This is what we ask below.
27
French towns (“communes”) could lend their land under ordinary lease s or gr ant longtime leases. The ordi-
nary” leases were l im ited to 9 years in 1791 for all communes, but exceptions could be granted by the national
administr ati on . The 9-year limit was soon extended to 18 years. Moreover, in 1859, the law was changed so that
the ordinary leases of the communes were a minimum of 9 years and a maximum of 27. Furthermore, c ommunes
had the right to deliver lifelong leases on commons.
24
5.3 Emigration during the Revolution and Human Capital Accumulation
This section examines whether the positive ect of emigration on the standards of living in the
long run can be explained by its impact on the evolution of human capital accumulation of each
département before and after World War II.
5.3.1 The ect of Emigrés on Human Capital Accumulation
For the period before World War II, our empirical analysis focuses on the decadal averages between
the 1840s and the 1930s of the share of illiterate French army conscripts, that is, 20-year-old men
who reported for military service in the département where their father lived and who could
neither read nor write. In the 2SLS regressions reported in Table 9, we nd that emigration has a
negative ect on the share of illiterate conscripts throughout the period. This ect is signi…cant
at the 10% level in the 1840s and 1870s, and barely insigni…cant during the 1850s (p-value=0.12),
1860s (p-value=0.23), 1880s (p-value=0.17), and 1890s (p-value=0.27). The negative ect of
emigration on illiteracy is consistently signi…cant for the generations of c onsc ripts in the 1900s,
1910s, and 1930s, that is, for the 20-year-old men who would have bene…ted from the adoption
of the 1881-1882 laws on free and mandatory schooling until age 13. This pattern suggests that
in high-emigration areas throughout the 19th century, and despite their limited means, parents
attempted to invest relatively more in th e human capital of their children compared to the more
a- uent, low emigration départements. This tendency toward higher literacy rates becomes more
evident after 1881-1882 when schooling becomes free and man datory until the age of 13. Below
we discuss how this pattern may be attributed to the relatively low returns to agricultural labor
compared to the other sectors of the economy.
Since World War II, départements which experienced large emigration waves during the
French Revolution have maintained their human capital advantage already apparent at the turn
of the 20th century. This can be seen in Panels A and B of Figure D.5, where we plot the
co cients associated with the share of émigrés in 2SLS regressions. In Panel A the depend ent
variable is the share of men ages 16-24 with only a high-school degree in 1968, 1975, 1982, 1990,
1999 and 2010, whereas in Panel B the dependent variable is the share of men ages 16-24 with
a college degree in the respective years. The share of émigrés has a p os itive and signi…cant
ect on the share of males age 16-24 with only a high school degree for 1975, 1982, and 1990.
Nevertheless, the share of émigrés has a positive and signi…cant ect on the share of men aged
16-24 with a college degree consistently between 1968 and 2010. These results suggest that since
World War II, human capital accumulation has been more intense overall in high-emigration
regions; although it seems as though there has been a slow convergence over the last two decades
in terms of high school completion rates, the relatively earlier transition to widespread literacy
25
in high-émigrés areas has conferred upon them an educational edge re‡ected in a greater ow of
college graduates to this day.
5.3.2 The Opportunity Cost of Education and Child Labor
Naturally, to understand why literacy rates di¤er across regions over time, one needs to tease
out the forces that shape the demand and supply of schooling locally. This is not an easy task.
However, one element that makes the case of France easier to analyze is the fact that primary
schooling became free and mandatory until the age of 13 after the adoption of the 1881-1882 laws.
Although this would imply that th e supply of schooling over time should become more uniform
across regions, we nd that high-emigration départements expe rience systematic under provision
of primary schools per school-aged (5-15 years of age) population until WWI. This is shown in
Panel A of Table D.18. A similar pattern is found in Panel B where the dependent variable
is the total public spending per pupil between 1876 and 1901. Panel C of Table D.18 actually
suggests that the limited supply of schooling re‡ected an overall und er provision of public goods
in high-emigration départements which also had a less dense transportation network up until at
least World War I. Moreover, given the role of the Church in the provision of schooling in France
before and after the Revolution (see Appendix A:3 for a discussion), it is worth pointing out
that Table D.19 shows that the temperature shocks in the summer of 1792 are not correlated
with variables that Franck and Johnson (2016) show to be good proxies for religiosity in France
before World War I. This lack of correlation between our instrument and the number of religious
communities in each département devoted to education, charity, and solely to religious purposes
in 1856 (from the 1856 French census), as well as the share of representatives in the lower house
of Parliament who voted against the separation of Church and State in 1905 (Franck (2010)),
suggests that the Church’s ability to provide education in the 19th century was uncorrelated with
emigration during the Revolution.
In light of these observations, the fact that literacy became more widespread in the high-
emigration regions which received overall fewer public goods (including public primary schools)
is all the more striking. But what may rationalize this pattern? We er two complementary
pieces of evidence.
First, a potential explanation for the rise in literacy across high-emigration areas from the
late 19th century onward may be partly attributed to the observation that one of the factors that
in‡uence human capital investments is the relative return of working in agriculture versus services
and industry. To the extent that literacy is arguably more complementary to non agricultural
occupations, a larger gap in labor productivity in favor of services and industry might act as
a catalyst for human capital accumulation. We already noted in Panel A of Table 5 that the
26
emigration wave during the Revolution had a negative impact on labor productivity in all sectors
of the economy until World War II. But what happened to the relative sectoral returns? In Panel
C of Table 5, we run 2SLS regressions where the depen de nt variable is the ratio of the value added
per worker in the non agricultural sector (i.e., industry and services) vis-à-vis the agricultural one
in 1860, 1930, 1982, and 1990. Emigration had a positive and signi…cant ect on this ratio at the
1% level in 1860 and 1930 in columns (1) and (2), suggesting the relative desirability of the non-
agricultural sector of the local economy in high-emigration départements. In columns (3) and (4),
the ect of emigration on the relative lab or productivities in 1982 and 1990 is insigni…cant. This
would be expected, as a supply response regarding human capital accumulation would eventually
lower the di¤erential wages between the agricultural and non agricultural sectors.
A second explanation for the early rise of literacy in the high-emigration areas can be traced
to the opportunity cost of ac quiring education. Besides the direct monetary cost of attending
school, a relevant but often underappreciated part of the decision on whether to acquire schooling
would be the forgone wages that a child would bring home. In the case of 19th-c entury France,
this outside option would be tightly linked to productivity in agriculture.
28
Taking into account
both the depressed labor productivity in the agricultural sector of high-émigrés areas until World
War II and the decline in the monetary costs of primary schooling after 1881, it is plausible to
expect individuals in high-émigrés départements to eventually accumulate human capital at a
faster pace instead of working in the agricultural sector.
We examine the conjecture that children and teenagers would be less likely to work in
the agricultural sector by using data from the 1929 agricultural survey. This survey provide s
information at the département level on the number of individuals below the age of 15 working
in agriculture. The 2SLS regression results reported in Table 10 show that in high-emigration
départements in 1929, individuals below the age of 15 were systematically less likely to work in
the agricultural sector, and presumably more likely to stay in school. The pattern is the same
whether the baseline is the overall workforce in agriculture, the number of daily agricultural
workers, the total number of daily agricultural workers (including foreign workers) below the age
of 15, or the total number of French and foreign daily agricultural workers above the age of 15.
In an ort to provide some historical background to the uncovered relationship between
returns to agriculture and the relative delay in human capital accumu lation in low-emigration
areas during the 19th century, we turn to the parliamentary deb ates which preceded the adoption
of mandatory schooling laws in France. In this respect, it is interesting to examine the debates
held in 1881-1882 when laws on mandatory schooling until age 13 were rst adopted, but also
28
The adverse ect of higher agricult ural productivity on human cap ita l accumulation has be en recently docu-
mented by Shah and Steinberg (2015) in the context of India.
27
in 1936 when mandatory schooling was extended until the age of 14.
29
Politicians who voiced
concerns regarding the implementation of the mandatory schooling laws in 1881-1882, such as
Jean-Edmond Laroche-Joubert who supported them or Ferdinand Boyer who opposed them,
thought that parents would refuse to send their children to school because they would be deprived
of the wages that their children would earn by working on nearby large farms (Journal ciel,
Debats, Chambre des députés 18-21 décembre 1880, pp. 36-75).
30
Laroche-Joubert represented
in the lower house of Parliament the Charente département, a low-e migration area with a high
ratio of large to small farms, while Boyer represented in the lower house of Parliament the
Gard département, also a low-emigration place with a median ratio of large to small farms. In
1936, the same type of argument was made by Henri Connevot, who represented Creuse, a low-
emigration département with a high ratio of large to small farms in the upper house of Parliament.
Speci…cally, Connevot was in favor of the law but expressed h is concerns that "in our rural areas,
very often, thirteen-year old children, as soon as they pass the primary school certi…cate, are sent
away to work by their parents, both boys and girls, to earn 100 f rancs per month the rst year
and 150 francs per month the second year. Th ese are therefore three thousands francs which are
lost by needy families. It will therefore be very di¢ cult to enforce the law, or it will be necessary
to grant allowances to those families." (Journal ciel, Débats Parlementaires, Sénat, 28 ju illet
1936, p 903. Translation is ours.)
Emigration, Landownership and C omparative Development Weaving together
the evidence so far, one may wonder whether the time-varying impact of émigrés on comparative
development may be quantitatively explained by the persistent di¤erences in the composition of
agricultural landholdings brought about by the emigration during the Revolution. In other words,
can the relative increase in the numbe r of small landowners account for the inverse relationship
between emigration rates and agricultural productivity in the medium run, as well as higher
human capital accumulation and b e tter economic performance after World War II?
We examine this hypothesis in Table 11 where we assess the change in the magnitudes
of our baseline ndings regarding the value added per worker in agriculture in 1860 (Table 5)
and GDP per capita in 2010 (Table 4) when we account for the ratio of farms ab ove 40 ha to
farms below 10 ha in 1862, which re‡ects the degree of concentration in landownership. First,
the association between the ratio of large to small farms and economic performance changes sign
29
In 1881-1882, as well as in 1936, most of the polit icians who supported mandatory schooling laws did so because
they thought that t he development of a state-fu nded secular sys tem woul d consolidate the Repu bli can regime by
weakening the Catholic Church. Conversely, the opposition t o the mand atory schooling laws was motivated by the
defense of the Catholic school system (see Franck and Johnson (2016) and the reference s therein).
30
Jules Ferry, who was the prime minister when the June 16, 1881, law was adopted a nd minister of education
when the Ma rch 28, 1882, law was pass ed, conceded that the implementation of mandatory schooling might be
problematic. (Journal ciel, Chambre des pus, 20 cembre 1880, p. 112).
28
over time, similar to the ect of emigration during the Revolution. A département dominated by
large farms in mid-19th-century Franc e was signi…cantly more productive in agriculture in 1862;
however, départements where the agricultural sector was populated by small- and medium-sized
farmers in 1862 have higher income per capita in 2000. Moreover, accounting for the composition
of agricultural holdings decreases the estimated co cient on the s hare of émigrés by roughly
half when the dependent variable is the value added per worker in agriculture in 1860, and by
approximately 40% when the variable of interest is GDP per capita in 2010. This implies that a
sizeable fraction of the obs erved reversal in the relationship between emigration rates during the
Revolution and subsequent economic performance is indeed driven by the nonmonotonic impact
of the concentration in landownership on comparative development.
The uncovered evidence is complementary to the mechanism p roposed by Franck and Galor
(2015), who argue that the early industrialization across French départements led to underinvest-
ment in education and lower employment in skilled-intensive occupations.
6 Conclusion
It is widely debated whether the 1789 Revolution enabled economic growth and industrialization
in France or stalled French development by consolidating an agrarian structure of small near-
subsistence farmers. In this study, we focus on the economic consequences of the local weakening
of the Old Regime, as proxied by the share of émigrés, mostly aristocrats, wealthy landowners and
clergymen, who ed France during the 1789-1799 period and whose property was con…scated and
sold by the revolutionaries. Our identi…cation strategy exploits local variation in temperature
shocks during the summer of 1792 to obtain plausibly exogenous variation in the share of émigrés
across French départements. Emigration intensi…ed in August and Se ptemb er of 1792 when the
Revolution took a radical turn. King Louis XVI was imprisoned, and a few weeks later, the rst
French Republic was proclaimed. At this critical juncture of the French Revolution, we show
that local shocks in the economic environment (captured by temperature shocks) are a strong
predictor of local emigration rates.
The study establishes that emigration during the French Revolution has had a nonmonotonic
impact on regional income per capita over the subsequent 200 years. While emigration had a
negative impact on income during the 19th ce ntury, it had a positive and signi…cant ect in the
long run. We suggest several mechanisms that may rationalize this pattern. First, in départe-
ments with more émigrés, there was more land redistribution. Large estates were fragmented into
smaller ones. This pattern may explain the archaic means of agricultural production in France
and its delayed industrialization during the 19th century. Second, the size and composition of the
local elites were shaped by emigration during the Revolution. High-emigration areas had f ewer
29
wealthy individuals as well as fewer large landowne rs.
We conjecture that the changes in the economic environment due to emigration during the
Revolution shaped the incentives for human capital accumulation over time. Speci…cally, we nd
that high-emigration départements have system atically higher literacy rates among the conscripts
even before the adoption of the laws regarding free and mandatory schooling in 1881-1882, and
this relationship further strengthens with respect to the generations born thereafter.
This early rise in literacy rates may be linked to two elements in‡uencing human capital
accumulation. First, départements with a higher share of émigrés in the population during
the Revolution are shown to have a larger gap in labor productivity in favor of the industrial
and service sectors up until World War II. To the extent that human capital is complementary
to non agricultural activities, raising the relative productivity of the latter would incentivize the
accumulation of basic literacy in high-emigration areas. Second, the opportunity cost of acquiring
education re‡ected in agricultural productivity was lower in the high-e migration départements.
Indeed, using data from 1929, we show that child labor in agriculture was lower in départements
with low-emigration rates and high-agricultural productivity, underlying the adverse dynamic
impact of high opportunity cost on school attendance. Since World War II, these départements
have kept their edge in education, as re‡ected in higher rates of college graduates today. As such,
the reduc tion in the share of wealthy individuals in the local population and the fragmentation
of agricultural property in the wake of the Revolution are consistent with studies predicting a
nonmonotonic role of equality in the process of development (Galor and Zeira (1993), Galor and
Moav (2004)).
Our study suggests several potential avenues for future research. For example, political
upheavals at di¤erent stages of development may shape economic trajectories and social pref-
erences across generations, and lead to the emergence of new political institutions over time.
Second, our study suggests that radical policies of land redistribution in agrarian societies can
have economic consequences that have a time- varying impact. Further research could explore
how policies speci…c to the industrial or service sector may in‡uence the long-term evolution of
human capital.
30
References
Acemoglu, D., D. Cantoni, S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson (2011): The consequences
of radical reform: the French Revolution,”American Economic Review, 101(7), 3286–3307.
Acemoglu, D., T. A. Hassan, and J. A. Robinson (2011): Soc ial structure and develop-
ment: a legacy of the Holocaust in Russia,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(2), 895–946.
Ado, A. (1987 [2012]): Paysans en révolution. Terre, pouvoir et jacquerie, 1789-1794. Société
des Etudes Robe spie rristes, Paris, France.
Aftalion, F. (1990): The French Revolution: an economic interpretation. Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK.
Agulhon, M., G. Désert, and R. Specklin (1976): Apogée et crise de la civilisation
paysanne,”in Histoire de la France rurale, ed. by G. Duby, and A. Wallon, vol. 3. Editions du
Seuil, Paris, France.
Arnaud, G. (1904): Histoire de la révolution dans le département de l’Ariège (1789-1795).
Edouard Privat, Toulouse, France.
Baldensperger, F. (1924): Le mouvement des idées dans l’émigration française (1789-1815).
Plon-Nourrit, Paris.
Balla, E., and N. D. Johnson (2009): Fiscal crisis and institutional change in the Ottoman
Empire and France,”Journal of Economic History, 69(3), 809–845.
Banerjee, A., E. Duflo, G. Postel-Vinay, and T. Watts (2010): Long-run health
impacts of income shocks: wine and phylloxera in nineteenth-century France,” Review of
Economics and Statistics, 92(4), 714–728.
Barral, J.-A. (1858): Drainage, irrigations, engrais liquides, tome troisième (2e édition). Li-
brairie agricole de la maison rustique, Paris France.
Bastien, P. (2006): L’exécution publique à Paris au XVIIIe siècle. Une histoire des rituels
judiciaires. Champ Vallon, Seysse l, France.
Bée, M. (1983): Le spectacle de l’éxécution dans la France d’Ancien Régime,”Annales, Histoire,
Sciences Sociales, 38(4), 843–862.
Biard, M. (1995): Collot d’Herbois: légen des noires et Révolution. Presses Universitaires de
Lyon, Lyon, France.
31
Blattman, C., and E. Miguel (2010): Civil War,” Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1),
3–57.
Bloch, M. (1929): Les plans parcellaires,”Annales d’Histoire Economique et Sociale, 1(1-2-3),
60–70,225–231,390–398.
Bluche, F. (1992): Septembre 1792: logiques d’un massacre. Robert La¤ont, Paris, France.
Bodinier, B. (1999): La vente des biens nationaux: essai de synthèse,”Annales historiques de
la Révolution française, 315(1), 7–19.
Bodinier, B., and E. Teyssier (2000): L’événement le plus important de la révolution, la
vente des bien s nationaux. Société des études robespierristes et Comité des travaux historiques
et scienti…ques, Paris, France.
Boisnard, L. (1992): La noblesse dans la tourmente, 1774-1802. Taillandier, Paris, France.
Bonin, S., and C. Langlois (1997): Atlas de la Révolution Française, Vol 10 - Economie.
Editions de l’Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, Paris, France.
Bonneuil, N. (1997): Transformation of the French Demographic Landscape, 1806-1906. Claren-
don Press, Oxford, UK.
Bosker, M., E. Buringh, and J. L. van Zanden (2013): From Baghdad to London: un-
ravelling Urban Development in Europe and the Arab World 800-1800,”Review of Economics
and Statistics, 95(4), 1418–1437.
Bouloiseau, M. (1972): La république jacobine, 10 août 1792 - 9 thermidor an II. Le Seuil,
Collection Points Histoire, Paris, France.
Bouton, C. A. (1993): The our war: gender, class and community in late ancien régime.
Pennsylvania State University Press, State College, PA.
Brissot, J.-P. (1792): Second discours de J.P. Brissot, dé pu té, Sur la nécessité de faire la guerre
aux Princes allemands, prononcé a la Société des Amis de la Constitution, séante aux Jacobins,
à Paris dans la séance du 30 dé cembre 1791. De l’Imprimerie d u Patriote François, Place du
Théâtre Italien, Paris.
Caron, P. (1935): Les massacres de septembre. Maison du livre français, Paris, France.
Carra, J.-L. (1782): Système de la raison: ou le prophète philosophe. Kearby, London, UK.
32
Caruana-Galizia, P. (2013): Estimating French regional income: departmental per capita
gross value added, 1872-1911,”Research in Economic History, 29, 71–95.
Cassirer, E. (1932 [2009]): The Philosophy of the Enlightenment. Princeton University Press,
Princeton, NJ.
Chateaubriand, F.-R. d. (1847): Opinion sur le projet de loi tendant a indemniser les an-
ciens propriétaires de biens fonds con…squés et vendus au pro…t de l’Etat, en vertu des lois
révolutionnaires, prononcée a la Chambre des Pairs, le 11 avril 1825,” in Oeuvres Complètes
Tome Deuxième (Oeuvres Politiques). Firmin Didot, Paris, France.
Chevallier, E. (1887): Les salaires au XIXe siècle. Arthur Rousseau, Paris, France.
Coale, A. J. (1969): The Decline of Fertility in Europe from the French Revolution to World
War II,”in Fertility and Family Planning : A World View, ed. by S. Behrman, L. Corsa, and
R. Freedman, pp. 3–24, Ann Arbor, MI. University of Michigan Press.
Cobb, R. (1972): Reactions to the French Revolution. Oxford University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Cobban, A. (1962): The social interpretation of the French Revolution. Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, UK.
Combes, P.-P., M. Lafourcade, J.-F. Thisse, and J.-C. Toutain (2011): The rise and fall
of spatial inequalities in France: a long-run perspective,” Explorations in Economic History,
48, 243–271.
Conley, T. G. (1999): GMM Estimation with Cross Sectional Dependenc e,” Journal of
Econometrics, 92(1), 1–45.
Crépin, A. (2009): Histoire de la conscription. Gallimard, Folio Histoire, Paris.
Crouzet, F. (1964): Wars, blockade, and economic change in Europe, 1792-1815,”Journal of
Economic History, 24(4), 567–588.
(2003): The historiography of French economic growth in the nineteenth century,”
Economic History Review, 56(2), 215–242.
Darnton, R. (1973): The Encyclopé die wars of prerevolutionary France,”American Historical
Review, 78(5), 1331–1352.
Daudin, G. (2010): Domestic trade and market size in late eighteenth-century France,”Journal
of Economic History, 70(3), 716–743.
33
David, P. A. (1975): Technical choice innovation and economic growth. Essays on American
and British experience in the 19th century. Cambridge University Press, New York, NY.
Dell, M. (2012): Path Dependence in Development: Evidence from the Mexican Revolution,”
mimeo, Harvard University, Department of Economics.
du Motey, H. R. (1893): Une paroisse rurale au duc
d’Alençon: Saint-Germain-de Clairefeuille, de s origines de la paroisse à 1790. E. Renaut-de-
Broise, Alençon, France.
Duc de Castries, R. (1966): La vie quotidienne des émigrés. Hachette, Paris, France.
Dupâquier, J., and M. Dupâqu ier (1985): Histoire de la démographie. Perrin, Paris, France.
Finley, T., R. Franck, and N. D. Johnson (2017): The ects of land redistribution:
evidence from the French Revolution,”Working paper, George Mason University.
Fiszbein, M. (2016): Agricultural diversity, structural change and long-run development: evi-
dence from US counties,”Working paper, Boston University.
France - Ministère de la Guerre (1839-1937): Compte rendu sur le recrutement de l’armée.
Imprimerie Nationale, Paris.
Franck, R. (2010): Economic growth and the separation of Church and State: the French
case,”Economic Inquiry, 48(4), 841–859.
(2016): The political consequences of income shocks: explaining the consolidation of
democracy in France,”Review of Economics and Statistics, 98(1), 57–83.
Franck, R., and O. Galor (2015): Is Industrialization Conducive to Long-Run Prosperity?,”
CESifo Working Paper Series No. 5354.
(2017): Technology-Skill Complementarity in Early Phases of Industrialization,” Na-
tional Bureau of E conomic Research Paper No. 23197.
Franck, R., and N. D. Johnson (2016): Can public policies lower religiosity? Evidence from
school choice in France, 1878-1902,”Economic History Review, 69(3), 915–944.
Franck, R., N. D. Johnson, and J. V. C. Nye (2014): From internal taxes to national
regulation: evidence from a French wine tax reform at the turn of the twentieth centu ry,”
Explorations in Economic History, 51(1), 77–93.
Furet, F. (1978): Penser la révolution française. Gallimard, Paris, France.
34
Furet, F., and J. Ozouf (1977): Lire et écrire. L’alphabétisation des français de Calvin à Jules
Ferry. Editions de Minuit, Paris, France.
Furet, F., and M. Ozouf (1988): Dictionnaire critique de la Révolution française. Flammarion,
Paris, France.
Galor, O., and O. Moav (2004): From physical to human capital accumulation: inequality
and the process of development,”Review of Economic Studies, 71(4), 1001–1026.
Galor, O., and J. Zeira (1993): Income Distribution and Macro econ omics,” Review of
Economic Studies, 60(1), 35–52.
Garrioch, D. (2002): The making of revolutionary Paris. University of California Press, Berke-
ley, Berkeley, CA.
Gay, P. (1966): The Enlightenment: an interpretation; the rise of modern paganism. Alfred
Knopf, New York, NY.
(1969): The Enlightenment: an interpretation; the sc ienc e of freedom. Alfred Knopf,
New York, NY.
Godechot, J. (1951): Les institutions de la France sous la Révolution et l’Empire. Presses
Universitaires de France, Paris, France.
Greer, D. (1935): The incidence of the terror during the French Revolution: a statistical
interpretation. Gloucester, MA: P. Smith.
(1951): The incidence of the emigration during the French Revolution. Gloucester, MA:
P. Smith.
Grigg, D. B. (1992): The transformation of agriculture in the West. Blackwell, Oxford, UK.
Grosfeld, I., S. O. Sakalli, and E. Zhuravskaya (2017): Middleman minorities and ethnic
violence: anti-Jewish pogroms in the Russian empire,” Paris School of Economics Working
Paper, 0(0), 00–00.
Gueniffey, P. (2011): La grande terreur: naissance e t mort d’une idéologie,” in Histoires de
la révolution et de l’empire, pp. 237–302. Perrin, Paris.
Guizot, F. (1829-1832): Histoire générale de la civilisation en Europe depuis la chute de l’empire
romain jusqu’à la révolution française. Pichon et Didier, Paris, France.
35
Haun, J. (1973): Visual quanti…cation of wheat development,”Agronomy Journal, 65(1), 116–
119.
Havard, O. (1911-1913): Histoire de la révolution dans les ports de guerre. Toulon. Nouvelle
Librairie Nationale, Paris, France.
Heckscher, E. F. (1922): The continental system: an economic interpretation. Clarendon
Press, Oxford, UK.
Heller, H. (2006): The Bourgeois Revolution in France, 1789-1815. Be rgham Books, New York,
NY.
Henderson, W. (1957): The Anglo-French commercial treaty of 1786,” Economic History
Review, 10(1), 104–112.
Hidalgo, F. D., S. Naidu, S. Nichter, and N. Richardson (2010): Economic Determi-
nants of Land Invasions,”Review of Economics and Statistics, 92(3), 505–523.
Higonnet, P. L.-R. (1981): Class, ideology, and the rights of nobles during the French
Revolution. Clarendon Press, Oxford, UK.
Hobsbawm, E. J. (1990): Echoes of the Marseillaise: two centuries look back on the French
Revolution. Verso Books, London, UK.
Hoffman, P. T., G. Postel-Vinay, and J.-L. Rosenthal (2000): Priceless Markets. The
Political Economy of Credit in Paris, 1660-1870. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.
Hyslop, B. F. (1934): French nationalism in 1789 according to the General Cahiers. Columbia
University Press, New York, NY.
Israel, J. (2014): Revolutionary ideas: an intellectual history of the French Revolution from
the rights of man to Robespierre. Princeton University Press, Princeton,NJ.
Jaurès, J. (1901-1903): Histoire socialiste de la Révolution française, Edition revue par A.
Mathiez (1922-1924). Editions de la Librarie de l’Humanité, Paris.
Johnson, H. C. (1986): The Midi in revolution. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Jones, C. (2002): The Great Nation : France from Louis XV to Napoleon 1715-1799. Penguin
Press, London, UK.
Jones, P. (1988): The peasantry in the French Revolution. Cambridge University Press, Cam-
bridge, UK.
36
Juhász, R. (2015): Temporary protection and technology adoption: evidence from the
Napoleonic blockade,”Working Paper.
Kaplan, S. L. (1984): Provisioning Paris - merchants and millers in the grain and our trade
during the eighteenth century. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY.
(1996): The bakers of Paris and the bread question 1700-1775. Duke University Press,
Durham, NC.
Koyré, A. (1948): Condorcet,”Journal of the History of Ideas, 9(2), 131–152.
Labrousse, E. (1933): Esquisse du mouvement des prix et de s revenus en France au XVIIIe
siècle. Librairie Dalloz, Paris, Franc e.
Labrousse, E., R. Romano, and F. Dreyfus (1970): Le prix du froment en France au temps
de la monnaie stable (1726-1913). Ecole Pratique des Hautes Etudes - SEVPEN, Paris, France.
Lebrun, F., J. Quéniart, and M. Venard (2003): Histoire générale de l’enseignement et de
l’éducation en France: de Gutempberg aux Lumières (1480-1789). Perrin - Collection Tempus,
Paris, France.
Lecarpentier, G. (1908): La vente des biens écclésiastiques pendant la révolution française.
Alcan, Paris.
Lefebvre, G. (1924): Les paysans du Nord pendant la révolution française. C. Robb e, Lille,
France.
(1962): The French revolution, vol. I: from its origins to 1793. Columbia University
Press, New York, NY.
Loutchisky, I. (1897): La petite propriété en France et la vente des bien s nationaux. Honoré
Champion, Paris.
Luterbacher, J., D. Dietrich, E. Xoplaki, M. Grosjean, and H. Wanner (2004): Eu-
ropean Seasonal and Annual Temperature Variability, Trends, and Extremes Since 1500,”
Science, 303(5663), 1499–1503.
(2006): European Seasonal Temperature Reconstructions,” IGBP PAGES/World
Data Center for Paleoclimatology Data Contribution Series No. 2006-060, NOAA/NCDC
Paleoclimatology Program.
Maddison, A. (2001): The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Development Centre
Studies, OECD.
37
Marion, M. (1908): La vente des biens nationaux pendant la révolution (avec étude spéciale
des ventes dans les départements de la Gironde et du Cher). Honoré Champion, Paris, France .
Markoff, J. (1996): The abolition of feudalism: peasants, lords, and legislators in the French
revolution. Pennsylvania State University Press, Pittsburgh, PA.
Martin, J.-C. (1987): La Vendée et la France, 1789-1799. Editions du Seuil, Paris, France.
(2006): Violence et révolution. Essai sur la naissance d’un mythe national. Editions du
Seuil, Paris, France.
Marx, K. (1843 [1970]): Critique of Hegel’s Philosophy of Right. Cambridge University Press,
Ed. Joseph O’Malley, London.
Mathiez, A. (1922-1924): La Révolution française. Librairie Armand Colin, Paris, France.
Mayeur, F . (2003): Histoire générale de l’enseignement et de l’éducation en France: De la
Révolution à l’Ecole Républicaine (1789-1930). Perrin - Collection Tempus, Paris, France.
Maza, S. (2003): The myth of the French bourgeoisie: an essay on social imaginary, 1750-1850.
Harvard Unive rsity Press, Cambridge, MA.
McPhee, P. (1999): Revolution and Environment in Southern France Peasants, Lords, and
Murder in the Corbières 1780-1830. Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK.
Mornet, D. (1933): Les origines intellectuelles de la révolution française. Librarie Armand
Colin, Paris, France.
Nassiet, M. (1993): Noblesse et pauvreté. La petite noblesse en Bretagne, XVe-XVIIIe siècle.
Presses Universitaires de Rennes, Rennes, France.
Nunn, N. (2008): The Long Term ects of Africa’s Slave Trades,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 123(1), 139–176.
Nunn, N., and L. Wantchekon (2011): The Slave Trade and the Origins of Mistrust in
Africa,”American Economic Review, 101(7), 3221–3252.
Palmer, R. R. (1941): Twelve who ruled: the year of the Terror in the French Revolution.
Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Pauling, A., J. Luterbacher, C. Casty, and H. Wanner (2006): Five hundred years
of gridded high-resolution precipitation reconstructions over Europe and the connection to
large-scale circulation,”Climate Dynamics, 26, 387–405.
38
Persson, K. G. (1999): Grain markets in Europe 1500-1900. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK.
Peyrard, C. (1996): Les Jacobins de l’Ouest. Sociabilité révolutionnaire et formes de
politisation dans le Maine et la Basse Normandie (1789-1799). Publications de la Sorbonne,
Paris, France.
Resnick, D. P. (1966): The white terror and the political reaction after Waterloo. Harvard
University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Rosenthal, J.-L. (1988): The fruits of revolution. Property rights, litigation and French
agriculture, 1700-1860. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Sargent, T. J., and F. R. Velde (1995): Macroeconomic policies of the French Revolution,”
Journal of Political Economy, 103(3), 474–518.
Schama, S. (1989): Citizens: a chronicle of the French Revolution. Random House, New York,
NY.
Scoville, W. C. (1953): The Hugenots in the French economy,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 67(3), 423–444.
Shah, M., and B. M. Steinberg (2015): Workforce and human capital investment: evidence
from India,”NBER Working Paper, 0(21543), 00–00.
Shapiro, G., and J. Markoff (1998): Revolutionary demands: a content analysis of the
Cahiers de Doléances of 1789. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA.
Shaw-Taylor, L. (2005): Family farms and capitalist farms in mid nineteenth-century Eng-
land,”Agricultural History Review, 53(2), 158–191.
Soboul, A. (1958): Les sans-culottes parisiens en l’an II: mouvement populaire et gouvernement
révolutionnaire, 2 juin 1793 - 9 Thermidor An II. Librairie Clavreuil, Paris, France.
(1962): Histoire de la Révolution française. Editions Sociales, Paris.
(1968): Survivances" féodales" dans la société rurale française au XIXe siècle,” in
Annales. Histoire, Sciences Sociales, vol. 23, pp. 965–986. JSTOR.
Squicciarini, M. P., and N. Voigtländer (2015): Human capital and industrialization:
evidence from the age of enlightenment,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130(4), 1–40.
39
Sutherland, D. (2003): The French Revolution and empire: the quest for a civic order. Black-
well Publishers, Oxford, UK.
Tackett, T. (1986): Religion, revolution, and regional culture in eighteenth-century France:
the ecclesiastical oath of 1791. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
(2015): The coming of the terror in the French revolution. Harvard Unive rsity Press,
Cambridge, MA.
Taine, H. (1876-1893): Les origines de la France contemporaine. Rob ert La¤ont - Bouquin s
[2011], Paris, France.
Taylor, G. V. (1967): Noncapitalist wealth and the origins of the French Rrevolution,”
American Historical Review, 72,(2), 469–496.
Thiers, A. (1823–1827): Histoire de la révolution française. Lecointre et Durey, Paris, France.
Tilly, C. (1964): The Vendée: a sociological analysis of the counter-revolution of 1793. Harvard
University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Tocqueville, A. D. (1856): L’ancien régime et la révolution. Michel Levy, Paris, France.
Toutain, J.-C. (1987): Le produit intérieur brut de la France de 1789 à 1982,”Economies et
Sociétés, 21(5), 1–237.
Vivier, N. (1998): Propriété collective et identité communale: les biens communaux en France,
1750-1914. Publications de la Sorbon ne , Paris, France.
Vovelle, M. (1985): La mentalité révolutionnaire. Sociétés et mentalités sous la révolution
française. Messidor, Paris, France.
Waldinger, M. (2014): Drought and the French Revolution: the ect of adverse weather
conditions on peasant revolts in 1789,”Working paper, London School of Economics.
Zadoks, J., T. Chang, and C. Konzak (1974): A decimal code for the growth stages of
cereals,”Weed Research, 14(6), 415–421.
40
A. Emigs as a Share of the
Dé partements Population
:
B. Average Temperature in
Summer 1792
C. Squared Devi ation from Tempera ture
in Summer 1792 (baseline 1767-1791)
D. Squared Deviation from Temperature
in Summer 1792 (baseline 1767-1791)
Partialing Out Ge ographic Controls
Figure 1: Share of Emigrés in Population and Summer Temperature in 1792 in French Départe-
ments
Source: Greer (1951),Luterbacher, Dietrich, Xoplaki, Grosjean, and Wanner (2004),Lut erbacher, Dietrich,
Xoplaki, Grosjean, and Wanner (2006 ); Pauling, Luterbacher, Casty, and Wanner (2006).
41
Somme
Pas de Calais
Seine Inferieure
Herault
No rd
Oise
Lo zere
Cantal
Vaucluse
Pyrennees Orientales
Aude
Creuse
Gard
Loire (Haute)
Eure
Vienne (Haute)
Ta rn
Calvados
Correze
Lo ire
Lot
Ind re
Aisne
Lot-et-Garonne
Aube
Ardennes
Seine et Marne
Ardeche
Gironde
Alpes (Hautes)
Manche
Landes
Charente
Aveyron
Cher
Marne
Meuse
Loiret
Seine et Oise
Puy de Dome
Drome
Yonne
Marne (Haute)
Eure-et-Loir
Ariege
Loir-et-Cher
Nie vre
Vienne
Allier
Charente-inferieure
Dordogne
Moselle
Gers
Indre-et-Loire
Garonne (Haute-)
Rhone
Pyrenees (Hautes)
Orne
Bouches du Rhone
Vosges
Isere
Sevres (Deux)
Saone et Loire
Pyrenees (Basses)
Savoie
Saone (Haute)
Ain
Cote d'Or
Seine
Sarthe
Rhin (Haut)
J u ra
Vendee
Loire-Inferieure
Mayenne
Meurthe-et-Moselle
Cotes du Nord
Rhin (Bas)
Doubs
Alpes (Basses)
Maine-et-Loire
Ille-et-Vilaine
Morbihan
Var
Fi n i s t e re
Alpes-Maritimes
-2 -1 0 1 2
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-.1 -.05 0 .05 .1
Squared Dev iation f rom Temperature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791)
Conditional on Geographic Characteristics
Temperature Shocks in 1792 and Emigration across French Departments
Somme
Pas de Calais
Seine Inferieure
Herault
Lo zere
No rd
Cantal
Ga rd
Aude
Loire (Haute)
Vaucluse
Ta rn
Calvados
Creuse
Pyrennees Orientales
Vienne (Haute)
Aube
Oise
Aisne
Lo ire
Lot-et-Garonne
Gironde
Alpes (Hautes)
Ind re
Manche
Eu re
Correze
Ardennes
Ardeche
Lot
Seine et Marne
Charente-inferieure
Marne
Charente
Drome
Ari ege
Marne (Haute)
Aveyron
Meuse
Puy de Dome
Yonne
Allier
Landes
Eure-et-Loir
Nie v re
Ge rs
Loir-et-Cher
Vienne
Cher
Indre-et-Loire
Garonne (Haute-)
Dordogne
Rhone
Vosges
Moselle
Savoie
Bouches du Rhone
Pyrenees (Hautes)
Orne
Seine et Oise
Sevres (Deux)
Saone (Haute)
Cote d'Or
Seine
Isere
Saone et Loire
Pyrenees (Basses)
Ain
Loiret
Doubs
Sarthe
J ura
Rhin (Haut)
Mayenne
Vendee
Loire-Inferieure
Meurthe-et-Moselle
Ille-et-Vilaine
Cotes du Nord
Alpes (Basses)
Morbihan
Rhin (Bas)
Maine-et-Loire
Var
Fi n i st e re
Alpes-Maritimes
-2 -1 0 1 2
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-.1 -.05 0 .05 .1
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791)
Conditional on Geographic and Pre-1789 Historical Characteristics
Temperature Shocks in 1792 and Emigration across French Departments
A. IV is the Squared Deviat ion from Temperature in
Summer 1792, Condi tional on Geographic Controls
B. IV is the Squared Deviation from Temperature in
Summer 1792, Condi tional on Geographic and Historical Controls
Figure 2: Temperature Deviation in the Summer of 1792 and the Share of Emigrés, Controlling for Geographic and p re-1789 Historical
Characteristics
Note: These gures depict the part ial scatterplots of the e¤ect of temperature shocks in the summer of 1792 on the share of émigrés in the population of
each Fr ench département . Pane l A presents the relationship with the squared deviati on from temperature in the summer of 1 792 (1767-1791) , while Panel B
reports the relationship with the absolute deviation from temperature in the summer of 179 2 (1767-1 791). Thus, the x- and y-axes in Panels A and B plot
the residuals obtained from regressing the share of émigrés in the populati on against the squared and absolute deviations from temperature in the summer of
1792, conditional on geographic and historical controls.
42
IV is the Squared Deviation from Temperature in
Summer 1792, Condi tional on Geographic and Historical Controls
IV is the Abso lute Deviatio n from Temperature in
Summer 1792, Condi tional on Geographic and Historical Controls
Figure 3: The ect of Share of the Emigrés on GDP per Capita in 1860, 1901, 1930, 1995, 2000 and 2010
Note: These gures. display the estimated co cients of the share of émigrés in the populat ion on GDP per capita 1860, 1901, 1930, 1995, 2000, and
2010 in the 2SLS regressions in Table 4, conditional on all the geographic and historical controls. Intervals reect 90% condence leve ls.
43
GDP per Capita in 186 0, Removing One "Nuts" at a Time.
IV is the Squared Deviati on from Temperature in Summ er 1792,
Conditional on Geographic an d Historical Controls
GDP per Capita in 201 0, Removing One "Nuts" at aTime.
IV is the Squared Deviati on from Temperature in Summ er 1792,
Conditional on Geographic an d Historical Controls
Figure 4: The ect of the Share of Emigrés on GDP per Capita in 1860 and 2010, Removing one "nuts" at a Time
Note: These gures display the estimated co cients of the share of émigrés in the populatio n on GDP per capita i n 1860 and 2010 in the 2SLS regressions,
conditional on all the geographic and historical controls, where w e remove one "nuts" at a time. The nomenclature of territorial units f or statistics (or “nuts)
is a s tandard for referencing administrative divisions within European Unio n countries. In this study, we use the rst level of “nutsfor France. The complete
2SLS regressions are available upon request. Interval s reect 90% condence leve ls.
44
-.8 -.6 -.4 -.2 0 .2 .4
Excluding Top 20%
Share of Emigres
Excluding Top 1%
Excluding Top 5%
Excluding Top 10%
Excluding Bottom 20%
Excluding Bottom 10%
Excluding Bottom 5%
Excluding Bottom 1%
-.8 -.6 -.4 -.2 0 .2 .4
Excluding Top 20%
Share of Emigres
Excluding Top 1%
Excluding Top 5%
Excluding Top 10%
Excluding Bottom 20%
Excluding Bottom 10%
Excluding Bottom 10%
Excluding Bottom 1%
GDP per Capita in 186 0, and the Di stributi on of Emigration
IV is the Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1792
Condi tional on Geographic and Historical Controls
GDP per Capita in 201 0, and the Di stributi on of Emigration
IV is the Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1792
Condi tional on Geographic and Historical Controls
Figure 5: The ect of the Share of Emigrés on GDP per capita in 1860 and 2010, Removing one the top and bottom 1%, 5% , 10%
and 20% in the Distribution of the Share of Emigrés
Note: These gures display the estimated co cients of the share of émigrés in the populatio n on GDP per capita i n 1860 and 2010 in the 2SLS regressions,
conditional on all the geogra phic and his torical controls, where we re move the top and bottom 1%, 5%, 10%, and 20% parteme nts in the distribution of the
share of émigrés. The complete 2SLS regressions are availa ble upon request. Intervals reect 90% condence le vels.
45
Ain
Ai sne
Al li er
Alpes (Basses)
Al pes (Hautes)
Al pes-Maritimes
Ardeche
Ardennes
Ariege
Aube
Aude
Aveyron
Bouches du Rhone
Calvados
Cantal
Charente
Charente-inferieure
Cher
Correze
Cote d'Or
Cotes du Nord
Creuse
Dordogne
Doubs
Drome
Eure
Eure-et-Loir
Finistere
Gard
Garonne (Haute-)
Gers
Gironde
Herault
Ille-et-Vilaine
Indre
Indre-et-Loire
Isere
Jura
Landes
Loir-et-Cher
Loi re
Loire (Haute)
Loire-Inferieure
Loiret
Lot
Lot-et-Garonne
Lozere
Maine-et-Loire
Manche
Marne
Marne (Haute)
Mayenne
Meurthe-et-Moselle
Meuse
Morbihan
Nievre
Nord
Oise
Orne
Pas de Cal ais
Puy de Dome
Pyrenees (Basses)
Pyrenees (Hautes)
Pyrennees Orientales
Rhin (Bas)
Rhin (Haut)
Rhone
Saone (Haute)
Saone et Loire
Sarthe
Savoie
Seine
Seine Inferieure
Seine et Marne
Seine et Oise
Sevres (Deux)
So mme
Tarn
V ar
Vaucluse
Vendee
Vi enne
Vi enne (Haute)
V osges
Yonne
-.4 -.2 0 .2 .4 .6
Share of Farms above 20 Hectares
-.1 -.05 0 .05 .1
Log GDP per Capita in 1860
Conditional on Geographic and Pre-1789 Historical Characteristics
Temperature Shocks in 1792 and Departemental-Level Income per Capita 1860
Ain
Ai sne
Al li er
Alpes (Basses)
Al pes (Hautes)
Al pes-Maritimes
Ardeche
Ardennes
Ariege
Aube
Aude
Aveyron
Bouches du Rhone
Calvados
Cantal
Charente
Charente-inferieure
Cher
Correze
Cote d'Or
Cotes du Nord
Creuse
Dordogne
Doubs
Drome
Eure
Eure-et-Loir
Finistere
Gard
Garonne (Haute-)
Gers
Gironde
Herault
Ille-et-Vilaine
Indre
Indre-et-Loire
Isere
Jura
Landes
Loir-et-Cher
Loi re
Loire (Haute)
Loire-Inferieure
Loiret
Lot
Lot-et-Garonne
Lozere
Maine-et-Loire
Manche
Marne
Marne (Haute)
Mayenne
Meurthe-et-Moselle
Meuse
Morbihan
Moselle
Nievre
Nord
Oise
Orne
Pas de Cal ais
Puy de Dome
Pyrenees (Basses)
Pyrenees (Hautes)
Pyrennees Orientales
Rhin (Bas)
Rhin (Haut)
Rhone
Saone (Haute)
Saone et Loire
Sarthe
Savoie
Seine
Seine Inferieure
Seine et Marne
Seine et Oise
Sevres (Deux)
So mme
Tarn
V ar
Vaucluse
Vendee
Vi enne
Vi enne (Haute)
V osges
Yonne
-.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3
Share of Farms above 20 Hectares
-.1 -.05 0 .05 .1
Log GDP per Capita in 2010
Conditional on Geographic and Pre-1789 Historical Characteristics
Temperature Shocks in 1792 and Departemental-Level Income per Capita 2010
A. IV is th e Squared Devi ation from
Temperature in Su mme r 1792
B. IV is the Squared Devi ation from
Temperature in Su mme r 1792
Ain
Ai sne
Al li er
Alpes (Basses)
Al pes (Hautes)
Al pes-Maritimes
Ardeche
Ardennes
Ariege
Aube
Aude
Aveyron
Bouches du Rhone
Calvados
Cantal
Charente
Charente-inferieure
Cher
Correze
Cote d'Or
Cotes du Nord
Creuse
Dordogne
Doubs
Drome
Eure
Eure-et-Loir
Finistere
Gard
Garonne (Haute-)
Gers
Gironde
Herault
Ille-et-Vilaine
Indre
Indre-et-Loire
Isere
Jura
Landes
Loir-et-Cher
Loi re
Loire (Haute)
Loire-Inferieure
Loiret
Lot
Lot-et-Garonne
Lozere
Maine-et-Loire
Manche
Marne
Marne (Haute)
Mayenne
Meurthe-et-Moselle
Meuse
Morbihan
Moselle
Nievre
Nord
Oise
Orne
Pas de Cal ais
Puy de Dome
Pyrenees (Basses)
Pyrenees (Hautes)
Pyrennees Orientales
Rhin (Bas)
Rhin (Haut)
Rhone
Saone (Haute)
Saone et Loire
Sarthe
Savoie
Seine
Seine Inferieure
Seine et Marne
Seine et Oise
Sevres (Deux)
So mme
Tarn
V ar
Vaucluse
Vendee
Vi enne
Vi enne (Haute)
V osges
Yonne
-2 -1 0 1 2
Ratio of 40ha Farms to 10ha Farms
-.1 -.05 0 .05 .1
Temperature Deviations in the Summer of 1792
Conditional on Geographic and Pre-1789 Historical Characteristics
Temperature Shocks in 1792 and Ratio of 40ha Farms to 10ha Farms in 1862
Ain
Ai sne
Al li er
Alpes (Basses)
Al pes (Hautes)
Al pes-Maritimes
Ardeche
Ardennes
Ariege
Aube
Aude
Aveyron
Bouches du Rhone
Calvados
Cantal
Charente
Charente-inferieure
Cher
Correze
Cote d'Or
Cotes du Nord
Creuse
Dordogne
Doubs
Drome
Eure
Eure-et-Loir
Finistere
Gard
Garonne (Haute-)
Gers
Gironde
Herault
Ille-et-Vilaine
Indre
Indre-et-Loire
Isere
Jura
Landes
Loir-et-Cher
Loi re
Loire (Haute)
Loire-Inferieure
Loiret
Lot
Lot-et-Garonne
Lozere
Maine-et-Loire
Manche
Marne
Marne (Haute)
Mayenne
Meurthe-et-Moselle
Meuse
Morbihan
Moselle
Nievre
Nord
Oise
Orne
Pas de Cal ais
Puy de Dome
Pyrenees (Basses)
Pyrenees (Hautes)
Pyrennees Orientales
Rhin (Bas)
Rhin (Haut)
Rhone
Saone (Haute)
Saone et Loire
Sarthe
Savoie
Seine
Seine Inferieure
Seine et Marne
Seine et Oise
Sevres (Deux)
So mme
Tarn
V ar
Vaucluse
Vendee
Vi enne
Vi enne (Haute)
V osges
Yonne
-1.5 -1 -.5 0 .5 1
Share of Farms above 20 Hectares
-.1 -.05 0 .05 .1
Temperature Deviations in the Summer of 1792
Conditional on Geographic and Pre-1789 Historical Characteristics
Temperature Shocks in 1792 and Share of Farms Above 20 Hectares in 1862
C. IV is th e Squared Deviation from
Temperature in Su mme r 1792
D. IV is th e Squared Devi ation from
Temperature in Su mme r 1792
Figure 6: Temperature Deviation in the Summer of 1792 and GDP per Capita in 1860 and 2010,
Controlling for Geographic Traits
Note: These gure s depict the partial sca tterplots of the associati on between the sq uared deviation of
temperature in the summer of 1792 ( 1767-1791) on GDP per capita in 1860 (Panel A), GDP per capita in
2010 (Panel B), the ratio of farms above 40 ha to farms below 10 ha in 1862 (Panel C), as well as the ratio of
farms above 20 ha in 1862 (Panel D). Thus, the x- and y-axes plot the residuals obtained from r egressing the
share of émigrés i n the population against the squared deviations from temperature in the s ummer of 1792 ,
conditional on the geographic and historical set of covariates.
46
Table 1: Emigrés during the Revolution
Panel A. Départements with High and Low Emigration
Five départements with largest Five départements with smallest
Number of émigrés Share of émigrés Number of émigrés Share of émigrés
Moselle 3827 Alpes-Maritimes 1.26% Loire 105 Loire 0.04%
Pyrenees Orientales 3854 Bouches-du-Rhone 1.80% Hautes-Alpes 105 Hautes-Alpes 0.09%
Bouches-du-Rhone 5125 Var 1.96% Cher 239 Cher 0.11%
Var 5331 Pyrenees Orientales 3.48% Haute-Loire 271 Rhone 0.11%
Bas-Rhin 20510 Bas-Rhin 4.56% Indre 278 Haute-Loire 0.12%
Panel B. Social Groups
Nobles 23% Priests 34%
Upper Middle Class 10% Lower Middle Class 3%
Working Class 6% Peasants 7%
Unidenti…ed 17%
Panel C. Correlations between Social Groups
Priests Nobles Upper Middle Class Lower Middle Class Working Class
Nobles 0.62
Upper Middle Class 0.46 0.56
Lower Middle Class 0.54 0.50 0.80
Working Class 0.58 0.52 0.71 0.89
Peasants 0.53 0.35 0.43 0.76 0.86
Note : The data on the social categories of émigrés report ed in Panels B and C are only availab le
for 69 out of the 86 parteme nts in mainland France. In Panel C, the correlations a re between the
natural logarithm of the variables.
Source: Greer (1951).
47
Table 2: Property Ownership before and after the French Revolution in 15 Villages in the District
of Avesnes in the Nord Département
Ownership
Before After
the Revolution (%)
Peasants 33.52 44.18
Bourgeois 4.73 25.68
Nobility 37.08 14.35
Church 18.80 0.03
Poor Institutions and Hospitals 0.69 0.58
Commons* 5.18 15.80
Note: * Before the Revo lution, there was no clear ownership of the commons.
Source: Lefebvre (1924, Tableau II, pp.892-893).
Table 3: First-Stage Regressions: Squared and Absolute Deviations from Temp e rature in Summer 1792
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
First stage: the instrumented variable is the Share of Em igres
Squared Devation from Temperature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) 4.450*** 5.929*** 6.159***
[1.052] [1.393] [1.499]
Absolute Devation from Temperature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) 2.365*** 2.612*** 2.590***
[0.497] [0.708] [0.770]
Geographic Controls No Yes Yes No Yes Yes
Historical Controls No No Yes No No Yes
F-stat (1st stage) 17.89 18.11 16.88 22.61 13.62 11.32
Observations 85 85 85 85 85 85
Note: This table reports the rst stage of the 2SLS regressions where the IV is the squared deviatio n
of standardized summer temperature i n 1792 (columns (1)-(3)) or the absolute deviation of standardized
summer temperature in 1792 (columns (4)-(6)) and where the instrumented variable is the share of émigrés in
the population (the dependent variable in the second st age of the 2SLS regression is GDP per capita in 1860
as shown in Tables 4 and D.12). The speci…cations in columns (1) and (4) do not include controls, those in
columns (2) and (5) only include geogra phic controls, while those in columns (3) and (6) include all co ntrol s.
The dependent variable is in logarithm. Robust standard errors are reported in brackets. *** signi…cant at
the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level.
48
Table 4: Emigrés on GDP per Capita (IV: Squared Deviation of Temp e rature in Summer 1792)
Panel A. GDP per capita 1860-1930
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)
OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS
GDP per capita 1860 GDP per capita 1901 GDP per capita 1930
Share of Emigres -0.0109 -0.0811*** -0.257*** -0.255*** -0.00861 -0.0681 -0.376** -0.376** 0.0340 -0.00614 -0.0532 -0.0505
[0.0322] [0.0304] [0.0853] [0.0749] [0.0388] [0.0534] [0.184] [0.181] [0.0289] [0.0288] [0.0542] [0.0443]
Adjusted R2 -0.011 0.585 -0.012 0.278 0.002 0.608
Geographical Controls No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls No No No Yes No No No Yes No No No Yes
Observations 85 85 85 85 83 83 83 83 85 85 85 85
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 5.929*** 6.159*** 4.967*** 4.895*** 5.929*** 6.159***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.393] [1.499] [1.267] [1.209] [1.393] [1.499]
F-stat (1st stage) 18.113 16.881 15.359 16.378 18.113 16.881
Panel B. GDP per capita 1995-2010
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)
OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS
GDP per capita 1995 GDP per capita 2000 GDP per capita 2010
Share of Emigres 0.0237 0.0478** 0.174*** 0.174*** 0.0238 0.0553** 0.201*** 0.196*** 0.0201 0.0493* 0.171*** 0.176***
[0.0195] [0.0212] [0.0525] [0.0541] [0.0199] [0.0222] [0.0600] [0.0617] [0.0225] [0.0254] [0.0602] [0.0607]
Adjusted R2 0.003 0.472 0.001 0.470 -0.005 0.466
Geographical Controls No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls No No No Yes No No No Yes No No No Yes
Observations 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 5.950*** 6.216*** 5.950*** 6.216*** 5.950*** 6.216***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.378] [1.487] [1.378] [1.487] [1.378] [1.487]
F-stat (1st stage) 18.647 17.476 18.647 17.476 18.647 17.476
Note: This table reports the e¤ec t of the s hare of émigrés in the population on GDP per capita in
1860, 1901, and 1930 (Panel A) and in 1995, 2000, and 2010 (Panel B) in OLS and 2SLS regressions. All
the de pendent variables are in logarithm. The IV in the rst stage of the 2SLS regressions is the squared
standardized deviation from temper ature in the summer of 1792. Robust s tandard errors are reported in
brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level.
49
Table 5: The ect of Emigrés on the Value Added Per Capita and the Workforce in Agriculture, Industry
and Services, 1860-1990
Panel A. Value Added per Worker in Agriculture, Industry and Services
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
1860 Value Added per Worker in 1930 Value Added per Worker in 1982 Value Added per Worker in 1990 Value Added per Worker in
Agriculture Industry Services Agriculture Industry Services Agriculture Industry Services Agriculture Industry Services
Share of Emigres -0.444*** -0.178* -0.193*** -0.478*** -0.0272 -0.0434 0.531*** 0.603** 0.517** 0.694*** 0.628*** 0.521**
[0.129] [0.0965] [0.0630] [0.144] [0.0523] [0.0443] [0.185] [0.250] [0.224] [0.227] [0.240] [0.223]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 85 85 85 85 85 85 86 86 86 86 86 86
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476
Panel B. Share of Workforce in Agriculture, Industry and Services
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Share of Workforce in
Agriculture 1860 Industry 1860 Services 1860 Agriculture 1930 Industry 1930 Services 1930 Agriculture 2010 Industry 2010 Services 2010
Share of Emigres 0.0514 -0.321*** 0.201* -0.103 -0.130* 0.139** -0.787*** 0.168** 0.151***
[0.0669] [0.115] [0.104] [0.0968] [0.0743] [0.0641] [0.215] [0.0684] [0.0501]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Ye s Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 85 85 85 85 85 85 86 86 86
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 17.476 17.476 17.476
Panel C. Ratio of Value Added per Worker in Industry and Services to Agriculture
(1) (2) (3) (4)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Ratio of Value Added per Worker in Industry and Services to Agriculture
1860 1930 1982 1990
Share of Emigres 0.243* 0.440*** -0.000431 -0.147
[0.126] [0.147] [0.135] [0.136]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 85 85 86 86
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.216*** 6.216***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.499] [1.499] [1.487] [1.487]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.881 16.881 17.476 17.476
Note: This table reports the e ¤ec t of the share of émigs i n the population on the value added per worker
in agriculture, industry, and services in 1860, 1930, and 1990 (Panel A) and the shares of the workforce in
agriculture, indus try, and services in 186 0, 1930, and 2010 (P anel B) in 2SLS regressions. All the depende nt
variables are in logarithm. The IV in the rst stage of the 2SLS r egressions is the squared standardized
deviation from temperature in summer 1792. Robust standard errors are r eported in bracket s. *** signi…cant
at the 1% l evel, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level.
50
Table 6: Emigrés and the Mechanization of Agriculture, 1862
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Fe rtilizer Ploughs Scari…ers Grubbers Searchers Horse Hoes Harrows Ridgers
per Worker in Agricultural Sector, 1862
Share of Emigres -0.413*** -0.199 -1.893*** -2.568*** -1.229** -0.746 0.003 -0.535
[0.147] [0.131] [0.560] [0.766] [0.551] [0.467] [0.301] [0.466]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881
(9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Seeders Root Cutters Tedders Reapers Croppers Steam-Powered Threshers Animal-Powered Threshers First Principal Component of Agricultural Tools
per Worker in Agricultural Sector, 1862
Share of Emigres -1.268** -0.366 -1.873*** -0.997 -0.695 0.394 -0.454 -1.799**
[0.545] [0.434] [0.698] [0.872] [0.754] [0.368] [0.514] [0.748]
Geographic controls Ye s Yes Yes Yes Ye s Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159*** 6.159***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499] [1.499]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881 16.881
Note: This table reports the e¤ect of the share of émigs in the population on t he number of agricultural instruments per agricultural worker in the
agricultural sector in 1862 in 2SLS regressions. All the dependent variables are in logarithm. The IV in the rst stage of the 2SLS regressions is the squared
standardized deviation from temperature in summ er 179 2. Robust standard errors are reported in bracke ts. *** signicant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level,
* at the 10% level.
51
Table 7: Emigrés and Electors in 1839 under the Censitory Regime of the July Monarchy
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Share of Electors Share of Landowners Share of Businessmen Share of Professionals Share of Civil Servants
in Department Population among Electors among Electors among Electors among Electors
Share of Emigres -0.546*** -0.101** 0.0917 0.147 0.425**
[0.168] [0.048] [0.098] [0.112] [0.172]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 81 67 67 67 67
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 7.733*** 7.872*** 7.872*** 7.872*** 7.872***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.514] [1.600] [1.600] [1.600] [1.600]
F-stat (1st stage) 26.093 24.195 24.195 24.195 24.195
Note: This table reports the e¤ect of the share of émigrés in the population on the share of voters in
the population and the shares of landowners, businessmen, professionals (i.e., lawyers and doctors), and civil
servants among those voters in 1839, under the censitory regime of King Louis Philippe (1830-1848), in 2SLS
regre ssi ons. All the dependent variables are in logarithm. The IV in the rst st age of the 2SLS regressions is
the squared standardized deviation from temperature in summer 1792. Robust standard er rors are reported
in brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% l evel.
52
Table 8: Size Distribution of Private Landholdings over Time and Share of Commons in 1863
Panel A. Emigres and Land Distribution
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Share of Farms above Ratio of the Number of Farms Share of Commons
40ha, 1862 20ha, 1862 40 ha to 10 ha, 1862 50 ha to 10 ha, 1929 50 ha to 10 ha, 2000 1863
Share of Emigres -1.535*** -0.873*** -1.603*** -1.755*** -0.768*** 1.720**
[0.453] [0.290] [0.481] [0.494] [0.266] [0.811]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 86 86 86 86 86 84
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 5.131***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.487] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487] [1.221]
F-stat (1st stage) 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.657
Panel B. Temperature Shock in Summer 1792, Farms in 1862, 1929 and 2000, and Commons in 1863
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Reduced Form Regressions
Share of Farms above Ratio of the Number of Farms Share of Commons
40ha, 1862 20ha, 1862 40 ha to 10 ha, 1862 50 ha to 10 ha, 1929 50 ha to 10 ha, 2000 1863
Squared Deviation of Temperature -6.599** -3.172* -6.724** -10.19*** -4.419*** 11.91**
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [2.676] [1.830] [2.903] [3.254] [1.570] [5.677]
Share of Church Property Sold in Department 536.9* 351.8* 598.8* 405.4 345.3 -631.0
[280.0] [203.0] [320.0] [408.7] [259.3] [563.4]
Squared Deviation of Temperature -11,099*** -5,562* -12,117*** -8,537** -9,867*** -1,781
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) * Share of Church Property Sold in Department [3,875] [2,969] [4,516] [4,191] [3,640] [6,594]
Adjusted R2 0.396 0.282 0.365 0.513 0.667 0.557
Observations 67 67 67 67 67 66
Note: Panel A of this table reports the ect of the share of émigs in the population on the share of farms above 40 ha and 20 ha in 1862 (col umns
(1)-(2)), on the ratio of farms above 40 ha to farms below 10 ha in 1862 (column (3)), on the ratio of farms above 50 ha to 10 ha in 1929 (column (4)) , on the
ratio of farms above 40 ha to 10 ha in 2000 (col umn (5)), and on the share of the commons w ithin the département in 1863 (column (6)) in 2SLS regressions.
All the dependent variables are in logarithm. The IV in the rst stage of t he 2SLS regressions is the squared standardized deviation from temperature in
summer 1792. Panel B of this table reports reduced-form regressions that include the share of Church land sold during the Revolution i n the 67 départements
where this information is avai lable (Bodinier and Teyssier, 2000) and the int eraction between this variable and the IV, i.e., the squared standardized d eviat ion
from tempe rature in the summer of 179 2. Robust standard erro rs are reported in brackets. *** si gnicant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% lev el, * at the 10 %
level.
53
Table 9: Emigrés and the Share of Illiterate Army Conscripts
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Share of Illiterate Conscripts by Decade
1840s 1850s 1860s 1870s 1880s 1890s 1900s 1910s 1930s
Share of Emigres -0.330* -0.285 -0.260 -0.460* -0.342 -0.318 -0.543** -0.605** -0.343***
[0.185] [0.183] [0.214] [0.241] [0.250] [0.290] [0.254] [0.246] [0.109]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 84 84 86 86 84 84 84 84 86
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.834*** 6.834*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 5.131*** 5.131*** 5.131*** 5.131*** 6.216***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.547] [1.547] [1.487] [1.487] [1.221] [1.221] [1.221] [1.221] [1.487]
F-stat (1st stage) 19.515 19.515 17.476 17.476 17.657 17.657 17.657 17.657 17.476
Note: This table reports the e¤ect of the shar e of émigrés in the populatio n on t he share of illiterate
French army cons cri pts, i.e., 20-year-old men who reported for military service in the d éparteme nt where their
father lived, in 2SLS regressi ons. All the dependent variables are in log arithm. The IV in the rst stage of
the 2SLS regressions is the squared standardized deviation from temperature in the summer of 1792. Robust
standard errors are reported in brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% leve l, * at the 10% lev el.
54
Table 10: Emigrés and French Workers below Age 15 in the Agricultural Sector, 1929
(1) (2) (3) (4)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Share of Share of French agricultural workers below age 15 among Ratio of
the agricultural workforce agricultural workers agricultural workers below age 15 agricultural workers above age 15
Share of Emigres -1.087** -0.794** -0.833** -0.804**
[0.444] [0.394] [0.344] [0.403]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 85 86 86 86
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.877*** 6.863*** 6.863*** 6.863***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.685] [1.678] [1.678] [1.678]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.656 16.724 16.724 16.724
Note: This ta ble repo rts the e¤ect of the share of émigs in the population on the share of French agricultural workers below age 15 among the agricultural
workforce (column (1)), agric ultural workers (column (2)), a gricultural workers below age 15 (column (3)), and agricultural work ers above age 15 (column (4))
in 2SLS regressions. Al l the dependent variables are in l ogarithm. The IV in the rst stage of the 2SLS regressions is the squared standardized deviation from
temperature in the summer of 1792. Robust standard errors are reported in brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% l evel.
55
Table 11: Can Land Redistribution Explain the Impact of Emigrés?
(1) (2) (3) (4)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
1860 Value Added per Worker in Agriculture GDP per capita 2010
Share of Emigres -0.444*** -0.224** 0.176*** 0.105**
[0.129] [0.0988] [0.0607] [0.0413]
Ratio of 40ha Farms to 10ha Farms, 1862 0.134*** -0.0441***
[0.0367] [0.0160]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 85 85 86 86
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.159*** 7.309*** 6.216*** 7.446***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.499] [1.405] [1.487] [1.403]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.881 27.071 17.476 28.147
Note: This table reports the e¤ect of the share of émigrés in the population on the value added per worker in a griculture in 1860 (as in Table 5) and on
GDP per ca pita in 2010 (as in Table 4), ac coun ting for the ratio of farms above 40 ha to farms below 10 ha in 1862 in columns (2 ) and (4) in 2SLS regressions.
All the dependent variables are in logarithm. The IV in the rst stage of the 2SLS regre ssi ons is the square d standardized d eviat ion from temperatur e in the
summer of 1792. Robust standard errors are re ported in brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% leve l, * at the 10% level.
56
Appendix for Online Publication
A. Historical Background
A.1 The Origins of the French Revolution
Most historians now agree on the immediate causes of the French Revolution. The Old
Regime experienced a scal crisis in the late 1780s, resulting mainly from the French support to
the American War of Independence and by an ine¢ cient tax system in need of reform. The c risis
was exacerbated by two consecutive years of bad harvests and peasant revolts in 1788 and 1789
(see, e.g., Aftalion (1990), Balla and Johnson (2009), Waldinger (2014), and Tackett (2015) for a
discussion).
However, the structural causes of the French Revolution are still debated. Some historians
emphasize the rise of the bourgeoisie, while others stress the con‡icts within the nobility and
the Third Estate (Furet (1978)). Such a debate is keenly related to the importance of ideas in
the unfolding of events and, in particular, to the violence of the French Revolution, leading to a
declaration of war against foreign countries and to internal con‡ict. As noted by Israel (2014),
there were revolts before and after the French Revolution which did not have major political and
economic consequences: it is therefore di¢ cult to argue that ideas would not p lay a role in the
deeper roots of the French Revolution and the outbreak of revolutionary violence. These ideas
include the development of a French national identity encouraged by the monarchy in the wake
of the defeat in the Seven Years’War (1756-1763) as well as the development over two centuries
of a national state with a centralized administration which gradually rendered local aristocrats,
who used to serve as local justice cers, costly and redundant (Tocqueville (1856)). These ideas
also relate to the Enlightenment philosophers and their revolutionary disciples. Enlightenment
philosophers dismissed revealed religions and criticized existing social and political hierarchies,
but they were oblivious to their optimistic faith in reason, nature and people.
31
When every
revolutionary thought that he represented the people”, and that his actions were guided by the
will of the people,”he then felt legitimized in using violence so that his revolutionary ideas would
prevail.
32
According to Furet (1978) this also explains the obsession of revolutionaries with trea-
sons and conspiracies: the revolution was inherently good, seen as freeing the entire population
from tyranny, and therefore, only hidden an d evil forces would oppose it. This revolutionary
31
On the philosophy of Enlightenment, see, f or example, Cassirer (1932 [2009]) as well as Gay (1966 ) and Gay
(1969). On the relationship between Enlightenment philosophy and the revolution, see notably Mornet (1 933) and
Martin (2006), and speci…cally Koyré (1948) on Condorcet, the only Enlightenment p hilosopher who took an active
part in the Revolution.
32
For instance, in 1782, future revolutionary leader Jean-Louis Carra published a book where he advoc ated
violence to overthrow superstition and “tyranny” (Carra (1782)). Another telling example can be found in the
Instruction written to the s oldiers o n 26 Brumaire Year II ( November 16, 1793) by Comité du Salut Public m ember
Jean-Mar ie Collot d’Herbois as they quelled the revolt in Lyon: “Everything is permissible for those who act in
service of the revolution”(Tout est permis pour ceux qui agissent dans le sens de la révolution). On the repression
carried ou t by Collot d’Herbois in Lyon , see, for example, Palmer (1941) an d Biard (1995).
57
mentality” (Vovelle (1985)) may rationalize the revolutionaries’obsession with nding culprits
and conspirators among their royalist opponents but also amidst the most devoted in their own
ranks.
33
A.2 The “Second Revolution”
During the summer of 1792, France experienced political turmoil and widespread agitation
that would lead to the collapse of the House of Bourbon. The Legislative Assembly had declared
war on April 20, 1792, against Austria. France attacked th e Aus trian Netherlands, but Prussia
joined forces with Austria and, at rst, the French army su¤ered losses. These foreign armies were
thought to be preparing to invade France, and rumors spread among the Parisian population that
nobles and priests were plotting with the leaders of the foreign armies. Th e Brunswick Manifesto,
issued on July 25, 1792, by Charles William Ferdinand, Duke of Brunswick and commander of the
armies allied against France, heightened the tensions as it threatened that Parisian civilians would
be held personally respon sible and tried in a military court if the members of the French royal
family were harmed. While this measure was intended to intimidate the French revolutionaries,
it on ly galvanized them. On August 10; 1792, the radical Parisian sans-culottes, supported by
volunteers from Brittany and the South of France, attacked the King’s castle and jailed Louis
XVI and his family. As rumors of foreign invasion intensi…ed, aristocrats and priests who were
thought to be a part of the conspiracy against the revolution became targets of violence.
On September 2-6, 1792, the radical sans-culottes, who were mostly of bourgeois back-
ground, slaughtered aristocrats and clergy members who were imprisoned in the Parisian jails,
along with petty thieves and prostitutes (Soboul (1958)). Similar episodes of violence occurred
in various parts of France (Caron (1935), Bluche (1992), M arko¤ (1996)). Some of this violence
was caused by peasant revolts, which were exacerbated by the July 22, 1792, decree pertaining
to mass conscription, as well as by the June 18, 1792, and August 25, 1792, laws, which subor-
dinated the payments of feudal dues to the presentation of the primal titles (Peyrard (1996), pp.
107-114, Ado (1987 [2012]), pp. 311-322). The war took a di¤erent turn with the victory of the
French revolutionary army on September 20; 1792, at Valmy. T he following day, the monarchy
was abolished and the republic proclaimed. The trial of King Louis XVI began on December 11,
1792. On January 20, 1793, the members of the National Convention voted 380 to 310 in favor
of his execution, and he was guillotined the next day.
A.3 Pri mary School Provision during the 19th Century
Under the Old Regime, the French state barely intervened in primary schooling and let the
Church organize its own network of primary schools (Lebrun, Quéniart, and Venard (2003)). The
33
As revolutio nary leader Jacques -Pierre Br iss ot exclaimed in a 1791 speech: “We need great treasons (Nous
avons besoin de grandes trahiso ns) (Brissot (1792)).
58
French Revolution harmed the Catholic school system, but the successive French rulers between
1799 and 1830 (Napoléon Bonaparte, 1799-1815, Louis XVIII, 1815-1824, Charles X, 1824-1830)
enabled the Church to (re-)develop its educational network. After 1830, the French political
regimes (the July Monarchy under King Louis-Philippe I, 1830-1848, the Second Republic, 1848-
1852, and the Second Empire, 1852-1870) were less favorable to the Church, but education laws
which were passed under those regimes fostered the development of Catholic schools. Thus,
François Guizot, who was King Louis-Philippe I’s prime minister, reshaped the organization of
schooling in France with the June 28, 1833, law that compelled all French communes to host
a primary school in their jurisdiction. This law enabled the Church to organize its own private
education system, but also to retain its control over public schooling. In particular, monks
and nuns could be employed as teachers in public schools while religious instruction remained
mandatory During the Second Republic, Education Minister Alfred de Falloux passed the March
15, 1850 law and the August 27, 1851, regulation that favored the Church since towns would
not have to fund a public school if a private (i.e., Catholic) school already operated in their
jurisdiction. Besides, all teachers had to ful…ll the duties prescribed by the Church. Finally,
Catholic secondary schools could compete with public secondary schools and could still receive
subsidies from the State and from the local governments.
Nonetheless, the political stance of the Catholic Church led to a con‡ict on education
against the French state which reached its apex after the establishment of the Third Republic in
1875. The Republicans, who opposed the Catholic Church for its support for the Royalist politi-
cians, rst weakened the Catholic educational system in the 1880s and 1890s before separating
Church and State in 1905. See, for example, Mayeur (2003), Franck and Johnson (2016), and
Franck and Galor (2017) for recent studies on this issue.
B. Temperature Shocks, Wheat Prices, Local Violence, and E migrat ion
B.1. The Impact of Temperature Shocks on Wheat Prices
In late 18th-century France, there is ample anecdotal evidence suggesting that abnormal
weather conditions would negatively impact crops and in particular wheat production, which was
the main crop cultivated and consumed in most French départements (Kaplan (1984), Kaplan
(1996)). Late spring and summer climatic conditions are important determinants of the winter
wheat yields (Triticum aestivum), which is planted in the fall and harvested in the summer or
early autumn of th e following year.
34
When local markets are not perfectly integrated, local wheat prices are likely to respond to
local yield uctuations, increasing the probability of social agitation when prices rise.
35
Anecdotal
34
On the growth and developme ntal st ages of wheat and the impact of weather conditions, see, for example,
Haun (1973) and Zadoks, Chang, and Konzak (1974).
35
On market integration (and la ck thereof) during the Revolut ion, see, for exa mple, Daudin (2010).
59
evidence from historians such as Soboul (1962) (pp.342-346) and Johnson (1986) (p.256) are
consistent with this reality.
36
Unfortunately, there are no comprehensive data on wheat prices
for 1792, but such data do exist for 1797-1800, that is, for the later p art of the Revolution
(Labrousse, Romano, and Dreyfus (1970)). This allows us to run panel-level regressions where
the price of wheat in each département is linked to the temperature shocks in the summer in that
département over the 1797-1800 period:
P
d;t
=
d
+
t
+
1
Z
d;t
+ u
d;t
;
where P
d;t
is the price of wheat in département d in year t, Z
d;t
is the temperature deviation
in département d in the summer of year t,
d
and
t
are département and year xed ec ts, and
u
d;t
is an error term for département d in year t. We consider several speci…cations for Z
d;t
including the squared and absolute deviation de …ned in the main text. For completeness, we also
constructed sep arate measures for positive (and negative) weather shocks to investigate whether
wheat prices di¤erentially respond to abnormally warm or cold summer temperatures.
We report the regression results in columns (1)-(5) of Table D.5. In the rst column, our
explanatory variable is the squared deviation from s tandardize d temperature; this speci…cation
does not include département xed ects so as to highlight the source of variation in our identi…-
cation strategy. In columns (2)-(5) we include département-spec i…c constants to account for any
time-invariant département-level characteristics: the main explanatory variable is the squared
deviation from standardized temperature in column (2), the absolute deviation from standard-
ized temperature in column (3), the positive and negative squared deviations in column (4) and
the positive and negative absolute deviations in column (5).
Reassuringly, increas es in temperature shocks at th e département level led system atically
to higher wheat prices during the 1797-1800 period, consistent with an economy composed of
relatively fragmented markets where local weather uctuations have material local economic
consequences. In Figure D.3 in Appendix D we plot the percentage change in yearly wheat prices
between 1797 and 1798 and the di¤erence in summer temperature shocks for the same period.
There is a c learly positive relationship.
B.2. The Second Revolution”: Violence and Emigration during the Summer
of 1792
To provide some support to the narrative that emigration in a département was p artly
driven by local violence resulting from abnormal weather conditions, we test whether the tem-
perature shocks in the summer of 1792 are signi…cantly related to local riots during the Second
36
In a study of th e Revolution in the South of France between 1789 and 1793, John son (1986 ) writes ( p.256):
The great concentration of violent episodes occurred in March 1789, July and August 1789, July 1791, March and
April 1792, and July and August 1792. All occu rred in either the sp ring or summer and were for the most part
the results of poor ha rvest s and food shortages.”
60
Revolution.”For this purpose, we use the data from Marko¤ (1996), who provides information on
local riots in August and September 1792, which we aggregate at the level of the département. We
have information on 82 departements. The average département has 53:30 riots with a standard
deviation of 193:65, a minimum of 0, and a maximum of 1; 489. In the OLS regressions, R
d
is
the log of the number of riots in August and September 1792 in département d, and Z
d;1792
is
the squared (or abs olute) deviation of temperature in the summer of 1792:
R
d
=
0
+
1
Z
d;1792
+ X
0
d
: + v
d
where X
0
d
is a vector of economic, geographical, and institutional characteristics of département
d, and v
d
is an error term for département d.
We report the regression results in columns (6) and (7) of Table D.5 in Appendix D.
Larger temperature shocks at the département level in the summer of 1792 lead systematically to
more riots. Figure D.1 provides a graphical representation of the statistical association implied
by column (6) in Table D.5. The evidence uncovered regarding the robust impact of abn ormal
temperatures on wheat prices and peasant revolts during the in‡ection point of the French Rev-
olution, namely the summer of 1792, increases our con…dence regarding the plausibility of our
identi…cation strategy.
B.3 First-Stage Robustness Checks: Temperature Shocks in the Summer of
1792 and Emigration
Given our reliance on the credibility of temperature shocks as a plausible source of varia-
tion for emigration during the Revolution, we have performed a comprehens ive set of robustness
checks. First, we show that the weather conditions in the su mmer of 1792 are the critical tem-
perature shocks during the Revolution for understanding emigration. Second, in an attempt to
mitigate concerns that our instrument correlates mechanically with preexisting measures of de-
velopment (or other large-scale events after the end of the Revolution), we amass ed a multitude of
alternative indexes of social and economic signi…cance, failing to nd any systematic association.
Speci…cally, emigration rates are explained neither by deviations from temperatures in the
spring, fall, or winter of 1792 in Table D.6, nor by deviations from temperatures in all the other
summers between 1788 and 1800 in Table D.7 and Figure D.2. Also, we show in Table D.8 that
squared and absolute deviations from standardized rainfall in the summer of 1792 do not explain
variations in the share of émigrés. In Table D.9 we report the rst-stage relationship between
the squared temperature deviation in the s umm er of 1792 and the share of émigrés accounting
for spatial dependence in the error structure (Conley (1999)). Moreover, in Table D.10, we show
that our rst-stage regression results are robust to using other baselines, such as a 50-year rolling
window based on summer temperatures between 1747 and 1791, a couple of xed 25-year windows
61
(1751-1775 and 1776-1800), or a xed 50-year window (1751-1800). Furthermore, in regressions
available upon request, we show that deviations from temperature in the summers from 1788 to
1800 do not systematically map into variations in the number of death sentences across France
during the 1793-1794 Reign of Terror (Greer (1935)).
37
We also test in regressions available u pon
request add itional speci…cations for the rst-stage regression, nding that measures of abnormal
temperatures other than the squared and absolute deviation of temperature in the summer of 1792
are less strongly correlated with the sh are of émigrés. In particular, we nd that the one- sided
deviation of temperature is only weakly correlated with the share of émigrés, thus suggesting
that both higher and lower than average temperatures in the summer of 1792 contributed to the
ight of the émigrés.
Moreover, we provide in Tables D.11, D.19, and D.20 several tests in support of the plausi-
bility of the exclusion restriction. These tests are meant to show that our instrumental variable,
the summer of 1792 temperature shock, is not correlated with variables which may potentially
be correlated with emigration rates and the evolution of income per capita in the medium and
long run. In Panel A of Table D.11, we focus on violence before 1789 and after 1815, as proxied
by the our war” of 1775, which is viewed as the last major s eries of riots triggered by bad
harvests and hunger before 1789 (Bouton (1993)), and by the post-1815 white terror”when the
royalist regime of Lou is XVIII arrested and se ntenced to death some of their revolutionary and
Bonapartist opp one nts (Resnick (1966)). In Panel B of Table D.11, we examine the demands of
the French population in 1789 as expresse d in the cahiers de doléances (Hyslop (1934), Shapiro
and Mark (1998)). We aggregate at the département level the numb er of times major political
and economic issues were mentioned in the cahiers de doléances.
38
Such issues include the ap-
proval of vote by head (a rst step toward democratic voting which was in opposition to the vote
by order as was the case under the Old Regime), state intervention in education, tendency to
socialism, as well as the abolition of guilds, feudal dues, and serfdom. In Panel C of Table D.11,
we measure human capital before the Revolution proxied by the share of brides and grooms who
could sign their wedding contracts over the 1686-1690 and 1786-1790 periods (Furet and Ozouf
(1977)). Lastly, in Panel D of Table D.11, we assess the p resen ce of the clergy that was hostile
to the Revolution, and the numb er of famous aristocratic families. We use the data from Tackett
(1986) on the share of clergymen who refused to take the oath in support of the Constitution
Civile du Clergé in 1791. As Tackett (1986) shows, this piece of legislation, which was hostile to
the Catholic Church (Godechot (1951)), re‡ected not only the views of the local priests at the
37
We nd that the unconditional relationship be tween tempera ture deviation in the summer of 1792 is signi…-
cantly and positively correlated at the 10% level with the share of death s entences d uring the Reign of Terror, but
that this is driven by the number of deat h sentences in one partement, Loire-Inrieure.
38
Cahiers de doances were redacted at the level of the baillage, which was an administra tive division of France
under the Ancien gime.
62
start of the Revolution but also those of the laypeople who pressured priests to accept or reject
the oath, thereby providing a measure of the religiosity of the local population. In addition, we
use information on the most prestigious noble families, as listed in the Almanach de Saxe Gotha,
in 1750, which can be viewed as proxying for the higher ends of the stock of regional political
and economic power (Squicciarini and Voigtländer (2015)).
39
In Table D.19, we show that temperature sho cks in the summer of 1792 are not correlated
with variables that proxy religiosity during the long 19th century (see Franck and Johnson (2016)
for a discussion): these are the number of religious communities in each département devoted to
education, charity, and solely to religious purposes in 1856 (from the 1856 French census), as well
as the s hare of representatives in the lower house of Parliament who voted against the separation
of Church and State in 1905 (Franck (2010)). Finally, we examine in Table D.20 whether our
instrument is correlated with the spread of the phylloxera in 1875 and 1890, a disease which was
harmful to vine roots but also to the health of the people living in the regions hit more harshly
(Banerjee, Du‡o, Postel-Vinay, and Watts (2010)).
All in all, while information prior to 1789 at the département level on the number of
priests, large landown ers, and land distribution is missing,
40
the results reported in Tables D.11,
A.19, and D.20 are reassuring since none of the potentially important variables is correlated with
our instrume nt. Indeed, if our instrument was systematically correlated with an economic and
political factor related to the land distribution or the composition of the population before the
Revolution, such a correlation would likely have been re‡ected in these observed traits including a
culture of violence before, during, and after the Revolution, complaints in the cahiers de doléances,
prerevolutionary human capital, local religiosity, and proxies for the presence of local elites.
39
The data of Fu ret and Ozouf (1977 ) and Squicciarini a nd Voigtländer (2015) do not cover all the French
départements and cannot therefore be included as part of the historica l contro ls in our baseline regressions.
40
W hil e some attempts were made to survey the French population under the Old Regime, it was only un-
der Napoleon Bonaparte’s rule in 1801 that t he rst systematic count of the French population was undertaken
(Dupâquier and Dupâquier (1985)). S till, it was only in 1851 that a survey o¤ered for the rst time systematic
information on the professions of the inhabitants at the local level. Moreover, t he cadastre, which registered prop-
erty ownership at the local level, was also given an impulse under Napoleon Bonaparte’s rule in 1807 but was only
completed in 1850 (Bloch (1929)).
63
D. Figures and Tables
Ain
Aisne
Allier
Alpes (Basses)
Alpes-Mar itimes
Ardec he
Ardennes
Ariege
Aube
Av eyron
Bouches du Rhone
Calvados
Cantal
Charente
Charente-inferieure
Cher
Correze
Cote d'Or
Cotes du Nord
Creuse
Dordogne
Doubs
Eure
Eure-et-Loir
Finistere
Gard
Garonne (Haute-)
Gers
Gironde
Herault
Ille-et-Vilaine
Indre
Indre-et-Loire
Isere
Jura
Landes
Loir-et-Cher
Loire
Loire (Haute)
Loire-Inferieure
Loiret
Lot
Lot-et-Garonne
Lozere
Maine-et-Loire
Manche
Marne
Marne (Haute)
Mayenne
Meurthe-et-Moselle
Meuse
Morbihan
Moselle
Nievre
Nord
Oise
Orne
Pas de Calais
Puy de Dome
Pyrenees (Basses)
Pyrenees (Hautes)
Pyrennees Orientales
Rhin (Bas)
Rhin (Haut)
Rhone
Saone (Haute)
Saone et Loire
Sarthe
Seine
Seine Inferieure
Seine et Marne
Seine et Oise
Sevres (Deux)
So m me
Tarn
Var
Vaucluse
Vendee
Vienne
Vienne (Haute)
Vosges
Yonne
-4 -2 0 2 4
Temperature Shock in the Summer of 1792
-.1 -.05 0 .05 .1
Riots in August & September 1792
Conditional on Geographic and Historical Characteristics
Temperature Shocks in Summer 1792 and Department-Level Violence in Summer 1792
IV is the Squared Deviati on from Temperature in Summ er 1792
Figure D.1: Temperature Deviation in Summer 1792 and Local Violence in Summer 1792, Con-
trolling for Geographic and Historical Characteristics
Note: This gure depi cts the partial scatterplot of the e¤ect of temperature shocks in the summer of 1792
on the logarithm of the number of riots in August and September 1792 in each French département. Thus,
the x- and y- axes plot the residuals obtained from regressing the logarithm of the number of riots in August
and Septembe r 1792 against the square d deviation from temperature in the summer of 1792, conditional on
geographic and historical controls.
64
Finist er e
Cot es du Nor d
M orbihan
I lle - e t - V ila in e
M anche
Loir e- I nf er ieur e
M ayenne
Vendee
M aine- et - Loir e
Calvados
Sevres ( Deux)
O rne
Sart he
Char ent e- inf er ieur e
Vienne
I ndr e- et -Loir e
Char ent e
Eure
Seine I nfer ieur e
G ir onde
Eure- et -Loir
Loir - et -Cher
Vienne ( Haut e)
Dor dogne
Seine et O ise
Indre
Pas de Calais
Somme
O ise
Nord
Seine
Ais ne
Lot - et -G aronne
Loir et
Seine et M arne
Landes
Creuse
M arne
Cher
Cor r ez e
Yonne
Ardennes
Aube
Nievre
G ers
M euse
Lot
M o s e lle
M eurt he- et -M oselle
A llie r
M arne ( Haut e)
Cot e d'O r
Rhone
Saone et Loir e
G aronne ( Haut e- )
Vosges
Pyrenees (Basses)
Puy de Dom e
Cant al
Loir e
Rhin ( Bas)
Saone ( Haut e)
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
Isere
Ariege
Rhin (Haut)
A in
Jura
Tarn
Loir e ( Haut e)
Doubs
Aveyron
Alpes ( Haut es)
Drome
Lozer e
Ardeche
Aude
Savoie
Pyrennees O rient ales
Alpes ( Bas ses)
Her ault
Vaucluse
G ard
Bouches du Rhone
Var
Alpes- M ar it im es
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-1 -.5 0 .5 1 1.5
Summer Temperature Shock, 1788
coef = .15870935, (robust) se = .185636, t = .85
Nord
Pas de Calais
Ais ne
Ardennes
Somme
O ise
M arne
Seine I nfer ieur e
M anche
M o s e lle
Calvados
Seine et M arne
Seine
Seine et O ise
M euse
Eure
O rne
Cot es du Nor d
M eurt he- et -M oselle
Rhin ( Bas)
Eure- et -Loir
Aube
Finist ere
I lle - e t - Vila in e
M ayenne
Sart he
Loir et
M orbihan
Yonne
M arne ( Haut e)
VosgesLoir - et -Cher
M aine- et - Loir e
Loir e- I nf er ieur e
Rhin (Haut)
I ndre- et- Loir e
Cot e d'O r
Vendee
Saone ( Haut e)
Cher
Sevres ( Deux)
Nievre
Vienne
Indre
Char ent e- inf er ieur e
Doubs
A llie r
Char ent e
Vienne ( Haut e)
Saone et Loir e
Creuse
Puy de Dom e
Jura
G ir onde
Dor dogne
Cor r ez e
Loir e ( Haut e)
Loir e
Cant al
Lot - et -G aronne
G ard
Landes
Lozer e
Ardeche
Lot
Rhone
Bouches du Rhone
Alpes- M ar it im es
G ers
Var
A in
G aronne ( Haut e- )
Aveyron
Vaucluse
Her ault
Tarn
Ariege
Savoie
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
Pyrenees (Basses)
Aude
Alpes ( Bas ses)
Pyrennees O rient ales
Drome
Isere
Alpes ( Haut es)
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-1 0 1 2 3
Summer Temperature Shock, 1789
coef = -.12435885, (robust) se = .0859038, t = -1.45
Vendee
I ndre- et- Loir e
Rhin ( Bas)
M eurt he- et -M oselle
Yonne
M arne ( Haut e)
Sevres ( Deux)
Loir - et -Cher
Loir e- I nf er ieur e
M aine- et - Loir e
Vosges
Cher
Char ent e- inf er ieur e
Vienne
Aube
Loir et
Cot e d'O r
Indre
M euse
Sart he
M o s e lle
M orbihan
Char ent e
Nievre
Rhin (Haut)
M ayenne
I lle - e t - V ila in e
Eure- et- Loir
G ir onde
Saone ( Haut e)
Cot es du Nor d
Vienne ( Haut e)Finist ere
A llie r
Seine et M arne
M arne
O rne
Seine et O ise
Creuse
Dor dogne
Seine
Eure
Lot - et -G aronne
Cor r ez e
Landes
Puy de Dom e
Seine I nfer ieur e
Calvados
Saone et Loir e
M anche
Doubs
O ise
Ardennes
G ers
Ais ne
Cant al
Somme
Lot
Loir e ( Haut e)
Loir e
Jura
Pas de Calais
G aronne ( Haut e- )
Lozer e
Nord
Rhone
Pyrenees (Basses)
G ard
Ardeche
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
Aveyron
A in
Ariege
Tarn
Bouches du Rhone
Her ault
Aude
Vaucluse
Pyrennees O rient ales
Drome
Savoie
Var
Alpes- M ar it im es
Isere
Alpes ( Bas ses)
Alpes ( Haut es)
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-.5 0 .5 1
Summer Temperature Shock, 1790
coef = .05017074, (robust) se = .36909154, t = .14
Seine et O ise
I ndr e- et -Loir e
Char ent e- inf erieur e
Eure- et -Loir
Seine I nfer ieur e
Seine
Sevres ( Deux)
Eure
Loir - et -Cher
O ise
Somme
G ir onde
Pas de Calais
Loir et
Char ent e
Seine et M arne
Vienne
Sart he
O rne
Nord
M aine- et - Loir e
Vendee
Ais ne
M ayenne
Calvados
Landes
Dor dogne
Loir e- I nf er ieur e
Lot - et -G aronne
M arne
I lle - e t - V ila in e
Yonne
M anche
Ardennes
Aube
Pyrenees (Basses)
Vienne ( Haut e)
M orbihan
Indre
G ers
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
Cot es du Nor d
M euse
Cor r ez e
Cher
Finist ere
Lot
Creuse
G aronne ( Haut e- )
M o s e lle
M arne ( Haut e)
Nievre
Cant al
Cot e d'O r
M eurt he- et -M oselle
Puy de Dom e
A llie r
Ariege
Tarn
Vosges
Aveyron
Lozer e
Loir e ( Haut e)
G ard
Saone et Loir e
Saone ( Haut e)
Aude
Her ault
Pyrennees O rient ales
Doubs
Loir e
Ardeche
Jura
Rhin (Haut)
Rhin ( Bas)
Bouches du Rhone
Vaucluse
A in
Rhone
Drome
Savoie
Alpes- M ar it im es
Var
Isere
Alpes ( Haut es)
Alpes ( Bas ses)
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-.2 0 .2 .4
Summer Temperature Shock, 1791
coef = .43920668, (robust) se = .66653364, t = .66
Cant al
Aube
Tarn
Nievre
M ar ne
Pas de Calais
Ariege
Ais ne
A llie r
Aveyron
Puy de Dom e
Cher
Nord
Somme
Yonne
Aude
Creuse
Rhone
G aronne ( Haut e- )
O ise
Loir e
Cor r ez e
M euse
Saone et Loir e
Pyrennees O rient ales
Cot e d'O r
Ardennes
Seine et M arne
Isere
M arne ( Haut e)
Lot
Indre
Loir e ( Haut e)
Lozer e
Seine
Drome
Her ault
Alpes ( Haut es)
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
Vienne ( Haut e)
M o s e lle
Seine et O ise
Ardeche
Loir et
A in
G ers
M eurt he- et -M oselle
Vosges
Saone ( Haut e)
Pyrenees (Basses)
Jura
Dor dogne
Savoie
Seine I nfer ieur e
Lot - et -G aronne
G ard
Loir - et -Cher
Doubs
Vaucluse
Eure- et -Loir
Eure
Landes
Vienne
Rhin (Haut)
I ndre- et- Loir e
Char ente
Rhin ( Bas)
Alpes ( Bas ses)
G ir onde
Bouches du Rhone
O rne
Sart he
Calvados
Sevres ( Deux)
Char ent e- inf er ieur e
M ayenne
M aine- et - Loir e
Var
M anche
Alpes- M ar it im es
Vendee
I lle - e t - V ila in e
Loir e- I nf er ieur e
Cot es du Nor d
M orbihan
Finist ere
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-.1 0 .1 .2 .3
Summer Temperature Shock, 1792
coef = 4.3363774, (robust) se = 1.050517, t = 4.13
Nord
M aine- et - Loir e
Vendee
M ayenne
Calvados
Pas de Calais
O rneLoir e- I nf er ieur e
Sevres ( Deux)
Ais ne
Sart heSomme
M orbihan
Char ent e- inf er ieur e
I lle - e t - V ila in e
Seine I nfer ieur e
Finist ere
Vienne
O ise
M anche
Eure
Cot es du Nor d
Char ent e
I ndr e- et -Loir e
Ardennes
G ir onde
Vienne ( Haut e)
Eure- et -Loir
Seine et M arne
Seine et O ise
Seine
M arne
Loir - et -Cher
Dor dogne
Indre
M euse
Lot - et -G aronne
Creuse
M o s e lle
Loir et
Cor r ez e
Landes
M eurt he- et -M oselle
Aube
Cher
G ers
Yonne
Rhin ( Bas)
M arne ( Haut e)
Lot
Vosges
Puy de Dom e
Cant al
A llie r
Nievre
Cot e d'O r
Saone ( Haut e)
G aronne ( Haut e- )
Rhin (Haut)
Loir e ( Haut e)
Saone et Loir e
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
Pyrenees (Basses)
Doubs
Ariege
Loir e
Tarn
Aveyron
Jura
Lozer e
Rhone
Aude
Ardeche
G ard
A in
Pyrennees O rient ales
Her ault
Bouches du Rhone
Var
Vaucluse
Drome
Alpes ( Bas ses)
Isere
Alpes- M ar it im es
Savoie
Alpes ( Haut es)
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-2 0 2 4
Summer Temperature Shock, 1793
coef = -.00209229, (robust) se = .08628495, t = -.02
M aine- et - Loir e
G ers
Char ente
I lle - e t - V ila in e
Lot -et -G ar onne
Sevres ( Deux)
Cot es du Nor d
M ayenne
Vienne
Dor dogne
Char ent e- inf erieur e
M anche
Loir e- I nf er ieur e
G ir onde
M orbihan
Ariege
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
G aronne ( Haut e- )
Pyrennees O rient ales
Vendee
Finist ereVienne ( Haut e)
Landes
Aude
I ndr e- et -Loir e
Lot
Sart he
Tarn
Calvados
Cor r ez e
Pyrenees (Basses)
Indre
O rne
Aveyron
Creuse
Her ault
Loir - et -Cher
Cant al
Eure
Seine I nfer ieur e
Lozer e
Eure- et -Loir
Cher
Puy de Dom e
G ard
Seine et O ise
Loir et
A llie r
Loir e ( Haut e)
Seine
Somme
O ise
Pas de Calais
Ardeche
Bouches du Rhone
Vaucluse
Alpes ( Bas ses)
Alpes ( Haut es)
Seine et M arne
Nievre
Drome
Var
Alpes- M ar it im es
Nord
Ais ne
Yonne
Savoie
Isere
Loir e
A in
Jura
Saone et Loir e
Cot e d'O r
Rhone
Aube
M arne
Doubs
M arne ( Haut e)
Saone ( Haut e)
Ardennes
M euse
Vosges
M eurt he- et -M oselle
M o s e lle
Rhin (Haut)
Rhin ( Bas)
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-.5 0 .5 1 1.5
Summer Temperature Shock, 1794
coef = .29518282, (robust) se = .22905571, t = 1.29
Alpes- M ar it im es
Var
Alpes ( Bas ses)
Alpes ( Haut es)
Bouches du Rhone
Isere
Savoie
Vaucluse
Drome
A in
Jura
Doubs
Her ault
Pyrennees O rient ales
G ard
Ardeche
Rhin (Haut)
Rhone
Aude
Rhin ( Bas)
Saone ( Haut e)
Lozer e
Aveyron
Loir e ( Haut e)
Loir e
Tarn
Vosges
Saone et Loir e
Ariege
Cant al
Puy de Dom e
M eurt he- et -M oselle
G aronne ( Haut e- )
Creuse
A llie r
Cor r ez e
Lot
Cot e d'O r
Vienne ( Haut e)
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
M o s e lle
M arne ( Haut e)
G ers
Dor dogne
Pyrenees (Basses)
Indre
Nievre
Lot - et -G aronne
Char ent e
Vienne
M euse
Cher
Sevres ( Deux)
Landes
G ir onde
Char ent e- inf er ieur e
Nord
Vendee
Loir e- I nf er ieur e
Ais ne
I lle - e t - V ila in e
Cot es du Nor d
Ardennes
M aine- et - Loir e
M arne
M orbihan
I ndr e- et -Loir e
M anche
Aube
Yonne
M ayenne
Pas de Calais
Finist ere
Somme
Loir - et -Cher
O ise
Sart he
Seine et M arne
Calvados
Loir et
O rne
Seine I nfer ieur e
Seine
Seine et O ise
Eure
Eure- et -Loir
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Summer Temperature Shock, 1795
coef = -.18221759, (robust) se = .194968, t = -.93
Alpes- M ar it im es
Var
Alpes ( Bas ses)
Alpes ( Haut es)
Bouches du Rhone
Rhin ( Bas)
Savoie
Vaucluse
Rhin (Haut)
Doubs
Isere
Drome
Jura
Nord
M eur t he-et -M oselle
M o s e lle
Vosges
Saone ( Haut e)
G ard
A in
Ardennes
Her ault
Ais ne
Ardeche
Pas de Calais
M euse
Pyrennees O rient ales
Lozer e
M arne ( Haut e)
Loir e ( Haut e)
Cot e d'O r
Somme
M arne
Saone et Loir e
Aude
Rhone
Aveyron
Loir e
Puy de Dom e
O ise
A llie r
Tarn
Aube
Cant al
Nievre
Cher
Seine et M arne
Creuse
Ariege
Yonne
Indre
Seine
Cor r ez e
Seine I nfer ieur e
Seine et O ise
Vienne ( Haut e)
G aronne ( Haut e- )
Lot
Loir et
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
Pyrenees (Basses)
Eure
Vienne
Loir - et -Cher
Dor dogne
G ers
Eure- et -Loir
M anche
Lot - et -G aronne
I ndr e- et -Loir e
Calvados
Char ent e
O rne
M ayenne
Landes
Sevres ( Deux)
I lle - e t - V ila in e
Sart he
M aine- et - Loir e
Loir e- I nf er ieur e
Cot es du Nor d
Char ent e- inf erieur e
G ir onde
Vendee
M orbihan
Finist ere
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Summer Temperature Shock, 1796
coef = -.33015176, (robust) se = .19397246, t = -1.7
Jura
Her ault
Rhin (Haut)
Vaucluse
Doubs
Rhin ( Bas)
Lozer e
Pyrennees O rient ales
Saone ( Haut e)
Ardeche
Loir e ( Haut e)
Aude
G ard
A in
Aveyron
Vosges
Alpes ( Bas ses)
Cant al
Puy de Dom e
M eurt he- et -M oselle
Tarn
Savoie
Ariege
Drome
M o s e lle
Bouches du Rhone
Creuse
Nord
Loir e
Cor r ez e
Saone et Loir e
A llie r
M arne ( Haut e)
Cot e d'O r
G aronne ( Haut e- )
Lot
Alpes ( Haut es)
Ais ne
M euse
Rhone
Alpes- M ar it im es
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
Ardennes
Vienne ( Haut e)
Isere
Indre
Pas de Calais
G ers
Cher
Pyrenees (Basses)
Nievre
Dor dogne
M arne
Var
Lot - et -G aronne
Somme
O ise
Landes
Vienne
Aube
Char ent e
Yonne
Seine et M arne
G ir onde
Seine
Char ent e- inf erieur e
I ndr e- et -Loir e
Sevres ( Deux)
Seine et O ise
Loir - et -Cher
Seine I nfer ieur e
Loir et
Vendee
Eure
M aine- et - Loir e
Eure- et -Loir
Loir e- I nf er ieur e
Sart he
M ayenne
I lle - e t - V ila in e
O rne
Calvados
M anche
M orbihan
Cot es du Nor d
Finist ere
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-.5 0 .5 1
Summer Temperature Shock, 1797
coef = .16653201, (robust) se = .19541229, t = .85
Alpes ( Haut es)
Isere
Drome
Savoie
Alpes ( Bas ses)
Rhone
A in
Saone et Loir e
Loir e
Vaucluse
Jura
Nievre
Cot es du Nor d
Alpes- M ar it im es
Finist ere
Rhin (Haut)
Doubs
I lle - e t - V ila in e
Saone ( Haut e)
Loir e- I nf er ieur e
Rhin ( Bas)
M orbihan
Var
Vosges
Cot e d'O r
A llie r
M anche
Ardeche
M aine- et - Loir e
Sevres ( Deux)
Vendee
M ayenne
Vienne
M eurt he- et -M oselle
Indre
Char ent e
M arne ( Haut e)
Vienne ( Haut e)
I ndr e- et -Loir e
Char ent e- inf erieur e
Cher
Sart he
Calvados
Creuse
M o s e lle
Dor dogne
O rne
Yonne
Loir - et -Cher
Lot
Cor r ez e
Bouches du Rhone
Tarn
Puy de Dom e
Aube
Lot - et -G aronne
Loir e ( Haut e)
Aveyron
M euse
G ir onde
Loir et
Aude
Eure- et -Loir
G aronne ( Haut e- )
Cant al
Ariege
Pyrennees O rient ales
Eure
G ers
Her ault
Lozer e
M arne
Landes
Seine I nfer ieur e
Seine et M arne
Seine et O ise
Seine
G ard
Ardennes
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
Pyrenees (Basses)
O ise
Ais ne
Somme
Pas de Calais
Nord
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-.5 0 .5
Summer Temperature Shock, 1798
coef = .11270558, (robust) se = .38155305, t = .3
Alpes ( Haut es)
Isere
Savoie
Alpes- M ar it im es
Alpes ( Bas ses)
Rhin ( Bas)
Drome
Rhone
M o s e lle
Rhin (Haut)
M eur t he-et -M oselle
Ardennes
M euse
Vosges
Var
Nord
M ar ne
M anche
Saone ( Haut e)
A in
M arne ( Haut e)
Doubs
Aube
Ais ne
Vaucluse
Cot es du Nor d
Finist ere
Calvados
Saone et Loir e
Cot e d'O r
Loir e
Pas de Calais
Seine et M arne
Jura
Somme
I lle - e t - V ila in e
O rne
Yonne
O ise
Eure
M orbihan
Seine I nfer ieur e
Nievre
M ayenne
Seine
Seine et O ise
Eure- et -Loir
Bouches du Rhone
Loir et
Sart he
Ardeche
Loir e- I nf er ieur e
M aine- et - Loir e
A llie r
Loir - et -Cher
I ndr e- et -Loir e
Vendee
Loir e ( Haut e)
Cher
Sevres ( Deux)
Puy de Dom e
G ard
Vienne
Indre
Char ent e- inf erieur e
Lozer e
Char ent e
Creuse
Vienne ( Haut e)
Cant al
Her ault
Cor r ez e
Dor dogne
Aveyron
Tarn
Lot
Aude
G ir onde
Pyrennees O rient ales
Lot - et -G aronne
G aronne ( Haut e- )
Ariege
G ers
Landes
Pyrenees ( Haut es)
Pyrenees (Basses)
-2 -1 0 1 2 3
Share of Emigres in Department Population
-4 -2 0 2 4
Summer Temperature Shock, 1799
coef = -.07915441, (robust) se = .05597598, t = -1.41
Figure D.2: Unconditional Correlation between the Squared Deviation from Tempe rature in
Summers 1788-1799 and the Share of Emigrés in the Population
Note: This gure graphs the rel ationship between the squared deviatio n f rom sta ndardized temperature in
all the summers between 1788 and 1799 and the share of émigrés in the population. It shows that the ne gative
and signicant relationship between the squared deviation from standardized temperature in the summer of
1792 and the share of émigrés does not hold for any other summer between 1788 and 1799.
65
AIN
AISNE
ALLIER
BASSES-ALPES
HAUTES-ALPES
ARDECHE
ARDENNES
ARIEGE
AUBE
AUDE
AVEYRON
BOUCHES-DU-RHONE
CALVADOS
CANTAL
CHARENTE
CHARENTE-INFERIEURE
CHER
CORREZE
COTE-D'OR
COTES-DU-NORD
CREUSE
DORDOGNE
DOUBS
DROME
EURE
EURE-ET-LOIR
FINISTERE
GARD
HAUTE-GARONNE
GERS
GI RONDE
HERAULT
ILLE-ET-VILAINE
INDRE
INDRE-ET-LOIRE
ISERE
JURA
LANDES
LOIR-ET-CHER
LOIRE
HAUTE-LOIRE
LOIRE-INFERIEURE
LOIRET
LOT
LOT-ET-GARONNE
LOZERE
MAINE-ET-LOIRE
MANCHE
MARNE
HAUTE-MARNE
MAYENNE
MEURTHE
MEUSE
MORBIHAN
MOSELLE
NIEVRE
NO RD
OISE
ORNE
PAS-DE-CALAIS
PUY-DE-DOME
BASSES-PYRENEES
HAUTES-PYRENEES
PYRENEES-ORIENTALES
BAS-RHIN
HAUT-RHIN
RHONE
HAUTE-SAONE
SAONE-ET-LOIRE
SARTHE
SEINE
SEINE-INFERIEURE
SEINE-ET-MARNE
SEINE-ET-OISE
DEUX-SEVRES
SOMME
TARN
VAR (SAUF GRASSE 39-47)
VAUCLUSE
VENDEE
VIENNE
HAUTE-VIENNE
VOSGES
YONNE
-.4 -.2 0 .2
Percentage Change in Wheat Prices Between 1797 and 1798
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Change in Summer Temperature Shocks Between 1797 and 1798
Unconditional Relationship
Wheat Prices Changes and Differences in Summer Temp. Shocks 1797-1798
W heat Price Changes, 1797-1798
Figure D.3: Wheat Price Changes and Di¤erences in Summer Temperature Shocks, 1797-1798
Note: This gure gra phs the relationship between the change in the summe r t emperature shocks between
1797 and 1800 and the percent change in wheat prices between 1797 and 1798.
66
-.05 0 .05 .1 .15 .2
1841
1851
1861
1811
1821
1831
1871
1881
1891
1901
-.05 0 .05 .1 .15
1841
1851
1861
1871
1811
1821
1831
1881
1891
1901
A. Fertility B. In fant Mortality
Figure D.4: Emigres, Fertility, and Infant Mortality, 1811-1936
Note: This graph displays the es timated co cients of t he share of émigs on f ertility and infant mortality between 1811 and 1901 in 2SLS regressions
where the IV is the squared deviation from te mperature in the summer o f 1792. All the dependent variables are in logarithms. Intervals reect 95% condence
levels.
67
-.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4
1968
1975
1982
1990
1999
2010
0 .2 .4 .6
1968
1975
1982
1990
1999
2010
A. Share of High-School Graduates among
Men Ages 16-24, 1968- 2010
B. Shar e of College Graduates among
Men Ages 16-24, 1968- 2010
Figure D.5: Emigres and the Human Capital of Frenchmen Ages 16-24, 1968-2010
Note: This graph displays the estimated co cients of the share of émigs on the share of high school graduate s among men ages 16-24 and on the share
of college graduates among men ages 16-24, 1968-2010 in 2SLS regressi ons. The IV is the squared deviation from temperature in the summer of 1792. All the
depende nt variables are in logarithms. Int ervals reect 95% cond ence levels.
68
Table D.1: Average Farm Size in France in 1862 and in the USA in 1860
Observations Mean Median Std.Dev. Min. Max.
Average Farm Size, France, 1862
Average Farm Size 88 23.12 18.12 13.14 4.57 62.83
Average Farm Size, Above Median Temperature Shock in Summer 1792 43 27.35 25.98 14.39 7.97 62.83
Average Farm Size, Below Median Temperature Shock in Summer 1792 45 17.02 19.08 10.46 4.57 49.80
Average Farm Size, Above Median Wheat Production 1862 44 29.86 28.51 13.20 8.56 62.83
Average Farm Size, Below Median Wheat Production 1862 44 16.38 14.47 9.05 4.57 49.27
Average Farm Size, USA, 1860
Average Farm Size 1944 336.17 562.54 218.64 10.78 15172.6
Average Farm Size, Above Median Wheat Production 1860 979 248.49 189.38 301.30 10.78 5610.0
Average Farm Size, Below Median Wheat Production 1860 964 425.42 291.56 728.33 11.71 15172.6
Average Farm Size, France 1862, Excluding Farms below 5 ha (=12.36 acres)
Average Farm Size, Excluding Farms below 5 ha (=12.36 acres) 88 102.99 78.59 91.33 36.32 705.58
Average Farm Size, Excluding Farms below 5 ha (=12.36 acres), Above Median Temperature Shock in Summer 1792 43 107.01 92.09 81.61 46.33 484.77
Average Farm Size, Excluding Farms below 5 ha (=12.36 acres), Below Median Temperature Shock in Summer 1792 45 99.16 75.48 100.51 36.32 705.58
Average Farm Size, Excluding Farms below 5 ha (=12.36 acres), Above Median Wheat Production 1862 44 108.74 78.98 107.87 42.29 705.58
Average Farm Size, Excluding Farms below 5 ha (=12.36 acres), Below Median Wheat Production 1862 44 97.25 77.91 71.91 36.32 484.77
Average Farm Size, USA 1860, Excluding Farms Below 9 acres
Average Farm Size Excluding Farms Below 9 acres 1944 354.74 231.11 639.89 12.14 17403.0
Average Farm Size, Excluding Farms Below 9 acres, Above Median Wheat Production 1860 979 256.89 194.18 310.37 12.14 5610.0
Average Farm Size, Excluding Farms Below 9 acres, Below Median Wheat Production 1860 965 454.00 309.44 841.41 26.00 17403.0
Note: Farm size is measured in acres.
69
Table D.2: Descriptive Statistics
Obs. Mean Std.Dev Min. M ax.
Explanatory variables
Share of Emigres in Population 86 0.0047 0.0064 0.00 0.05
Altitude 88 353.37 344.24 36.02 1729.22
Land Suitability 88 0.75 0.19 0.21 0.98
Latitude 88 46.54 2.11 42.60 50.49
Longitude 88 2.62 2.66 -4.06 7.55
Distance to Paris 88 357.07 178.66 0.00 693.86
Distance to Lyon 88 322.25 145.85 0.00 709.62
Distance to Marseille 88 448.50 210.44 0.00 879.23
Department Area 88 618807.00 148900.10 61087.20 1084890.00
Distance to Border 88 191.11 134.17 16.56 557.59
Distance to Coast 88 159.54 111.61 10.42 411.07
Temperature in Summer 1792 88 17.97 1.36 13.69 21.82
Lack of Commons in Department 88 0.32 0.47 0 1
Mechanical Mills 1789 88 0.08 0.31 0 2
Encyclop ed ie Subscribers 86 1.00 0.00 1 1.00
University in 1700 88 0.18 0.39 0 1
GDP per capita
GDP p er c apita 1860 87 498.18 144.20 273.00 1105.00
GDP p er c apita 1901 86 863.42 269.40 255.30 1816.40
GDP p er c apita 1930 87 6464.61 1500.21 4033.47 14109.90
GDP p er c apita 1995 88 17.64 3.17 13.23 38.83
GDP p er c apita 2000 88 20.37 3.99 15.49 47.72
GDP p er c apita 2010 88 24.65 5.60 18.36 63.22
Value added by wor kforce in each sector
1860 Value Added per Worker in Agriculture 87 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
1930 Value Added per Worker in Agriculture 87 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.02
1982 Value Added per Worker in Agriculture 88 3699.27 6510.40 225.52 55433.29
1990 Value Added per Worker in Agriculture 88 6069.24 6372.52 320.53 36589.30
1860 Value Added per Worker in Industry 87 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
1930 Value Added per Worker in Industry 87 0.02 0.00 0.01 0.03
1982 Value Added per Worker in Industry 88 5182.49 9865.68 304.84 88828.12
1990 Value Added per Worker in Industry 88 10524.74 23123.32 685.78 210220.80
1860 Value Added per Worker in Services 87 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
1930 Value Added per Worker in Services 87 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.02
1982 Value Added per Worker in Services 88 6716.78 12338.99 670.73 111846.40
1990 Value Added per Worker in Services 88 10455.12 20475.20 1034.12 186043.20
Workforce in agriculture, industry and services
Share of the Workforce in Agriculture 1860 87 0.63 0.16 0.01 0.89
Share of the Workforce in Agriculture 1930 87 0.45 0.16 0.00 0.73
Share of the Workforce in Agriculture 1982 88 0.13 0.07 0.00 0.34
Share of the Workforce in Agriculture 1990 88 0.09 0.05 0.00 0.26
Share of the Workforce in Agriculture 1999 88 0.07 0.04 0.00 0.19
Share of the Workforce in Agriculture 2010 88 0.22 0.09 0.00 0.47
Share of the Workforce in Industry 1860 87 0.22 0.11 0.06 0.52
Share of the Workforce in Industry 1930 87 0.30 0.11 0.13 0.63
Share of the Workforce in Industry 1982 88 0.34 0.07 0.20 0.49
Share of the Workforce in Industry 1990 88 0.31 0.06 0.15 0.44
Share of the Workforce in Industry 1999 88 0.26 0.05 0.14 0.36
Share of the Workforce in Industry 2010 88 0.23 0.03 0.14 0.33
Share of the Workforce in Services 1860 87 0.15 0.07 0.05 0.47
Share of the Workforce in Services 1930 87 0.25 0.08 0.13 0.54
Share of the Workforce in Services 1982 88 0.53 0.07 0.40 0.71
Share of the Workforce in Services 1990 88 0.60 0.06 0.47 0.76
Share of the Workforce in Services 1999 88 0.68 0.06 0.57 0.85
Share of the Workforce in Services 2010 88 0.53 0.09 0.37 0.86
70
Table D.3: Descriptive Statistics
Obs. Mean Std.Dev Min. Max.
Child Labor, Agricultural Survey, 1929
Share of French agricultural workers below age 15 in the agricultural sector 87 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.07
Share of French agricultural workers below age 15 among agricultural workers 89 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.06
Share of French agricultural workers below age 15 among agricultural workers below age 15 89 1.00 0.00 1.00 1
Share of French agricultural workers below age 15 among agricultural workers above age 15 89 0.07 0.05 0.01 0.26
Voters in 1839
Share of Electors in Departmental Population 82 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.01
Share of Landowners Among Electors 67 0.56 0.09 0.28 0.72
Share of Businessmen Among Electors 67 0.24 0.09 0.10 0.60
Share of Professionals Among Electors 67 0.11 0.04 0.04 0.24
Share of Civil Servants Among Electors 67 0.09 0.04 0.02 0.18
Share of Illiterate Conscripts
Share of Illiterate Consc ripts 1840s 85 0.37 0.18 0.03 0.71
Share of Illiterate Consc ripts 1850s 85 0.32 0.17 0.03 0.68
Share of Illiterate Consc ripts 1860s 88 0.23 0.14 0.02 0.54
Share of Illiterate Consc ripts 1870s 89 0.16 0.10 0.01 0.47
Share of Illiterate Consc ripts 1880s 86 0.11 0.08 0.01 0.38
Share of Illiterate Consc ripts 1890s 86 0.05 0.04 0.01 0.20
Share of Illiterate Consc ripts 1900s 86 0.03 0.03 0.00 0.15
Share of Illiterate Consc ripts 1910s 86 0.03 0.02 0.00 0.09
Share of Illiterate Consc ripts 1930s 89 0.05 0.01 0.03 0.08
Price of Wheat, 1797-1800
Wheat Price, 1797-1800 337 18.28 4.92 9.08 38.48
Share of Church Land Sold in Department
Share of Church Land Sold in Department 67 0.025 0.013 0.00 0.156
71
Table D.4: Descriptive Statistics
Obs. Mean Std.Dev Min. Max.
Average Temperature in Summers 1788-1800
Average Temperature in Summer 1788 88 18.48 1.38 14.18 22.31
Average Temperature in Summer 1789 88 17.37 1.3 12.66 20.87
Average Temperature in Summer 1790 88 18.09 1.43 14.03 22.04
Average Temperature in Summer 1791 88 18.16 1.37 13.93 21.95
Average Temperature in Summer 1792 88 17.97 1.36 13.69 21.82
Average Temperature in Summer 1793 88 18.49 1.44 14.72 22.53
Average Temperature in Summer 1794 88 18.38 1.33 14.16 22.13
Average Temperature in Summer 1795 88 17.39 1.38 13.23 21.34
Average Temperature in Summer 1796 88 17.37 1.37 13.21 21.34
Average Temperature in Summer 1797 88 17.84 1.41 13.58 21.93
Average Temperature in Summer 1798 88 18.48 1.37 13.83 22.13
Average Temperature in Summer 1799 88 16.82 1.32 12.88 20.77
Average Temperature in Summer 1800 88 17.86 1.42 13.39 21.57
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1788 (1763-1787) 86 0.82 0.53 0.02 2.27
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1789 (1764-1788) 86 1.34 1.00 0.00 3.73
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1790 (1765-1789) 86 0.27 0.29 0.00 1.25
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1791 (1766-1790) 86 0.15 0.15 0.00 0.51
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1792 (1767-1791) 86 0.05 0.07 0.00 0.30
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1793 (1768-1792) 86 0.97 1.17 0.00 5.45
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1794 (1769-1793) 86 0.43 0.44 0.00 1.61
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1795 (1770-1794) 86 1.35 0.47 0.32 2.17
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1796 (1771-1795) 86 1.48 0.49 0.31 2.28
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1797 (1772-1796) 86 0.32 0.34 0.00 1.35
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1798 (1773-1797) 86 0.48 0.19 0.00 0.96
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1799 (1774-1798) 86 5.25 1.64 1.68 9.31
Squared Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1800 (1775-1799) 86 0.26 0.32 0.00 1.29
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1788 (1763-1787) 86 0.85 0.32 0.13 1.51
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1789 (1764-1788) 86 1.05 0.48 0.01 1.93
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1790 (1765-1789) 86 0.44 0.28 0.00 1.12
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1791 (1766-1790) 86 0.33 0.21 0.02 0.72
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1792 (1767-1791) 86 0.19 0.14 0.01 0.55
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1793 (1768-1792) 86 0.81 0.56 0.01 2.33
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1794 (1769-1793) 86 0.54 0.37 0.01 1.27
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1795 (1770-1794) 86 1.14 0.22 0.56 1.47
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1796 (1771-1795) 86 1.20 0.22 0.56 1.51
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1797 (1772-1796) 86 0.47 0.31 0.01 1.16
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1798 (1773-1797) 86 0.67 0.17 0.02 0.98
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1799 (1774-1798) 86 2.26 0.36 1.30 3.05
Absolute Standardized Deviation of Summer Temperature 1800 (1775-1799) 86 0.41 0.31 0.01 1.13
72
Table D.5: Do Temperature Deviations In‡uence Loc al Food Prices and Local Violence?
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS
Price of Wheat 1797-1800 Riots in Aug. & Sept. 1792
Squared Deviation from Temperature 0.030*** 0.028***
in Summer 1797-1800 [0.006] [0.006]
Absolute Deviation from Temperature 0.063***
in Summer 1797-1800 [0.020]
Negative Squared Deviation from Temperature 0.029***
in Summer 1797-1800 [0.006]
Positive Squared Deviation from Temperature 0.159**
in Summer 1797-1800 [0.077]
Negative Absolute Deviation from Temperature 0.065***
in Summer 1797-1800 [0.020]
Positive Absolute Deviation from Temperature 0.200***
in Summer 1797-1800 [0.064]
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.077***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.536]
Absolute Deviation from Temperature 2.553***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [0.784]
Within R2 0.148 0.522 0.511 0.529 0.519
Adjusted R2 0.522 0.516 0.506 0.522 0.512
Department xed ects No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year xed ects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Clusters 85 85 85 85 85
Geographic controls Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes
F-stat 15.654 10.592
Observations 337 337 337 337 337 82 82
Note: This tabl e reports the ect of the absolute and squared deviat ion from standardized temperature
in summer 1797-1800 on the price of wheat in OLS regress ions with département - and ye ar-xed e¤ects in
1797-1800 period (columns 1-4) and in the summer of 1792 on the number of riots in A ugust and September
1792 accounting for geographic and historical control s (columns 5- 6). All the dependent variables are in
logarithm. Robust standard errors are reported in brackets. *** signicant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level,
* at the 10% level.
73
Table D.6: Robustness Checks on the First-Stage Regressions: Squared and Absolute Deviations from Temperature in Summer, Spring,
Fall and Winter 1792
Panel A: Squared Deviation from Temperature
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres in Population
Squared Devation from Temperature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) 6.159*** 10.26*** 5.983*** 7.203*** 11.48***
[1.499] [2.151] [1.533] [1.715] [2.295]
Squared Devation from Temperature in Spring 1792 (1767-1791) -1.029 3.221** 3.225**
[1.063] [1.317] [1.409]
Squared Devation from Temperature in Autumn 1792 (1767-1791) 2.807 1.600 3.661
[2.780] [2.348] [2.331]
Squared Devation from Temperature in Winter 1792 (1767-1791) -0.200 0.721* 1.119**
[0.444] [0.412] [0.508]
Geographic Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
F-stat (1st stage) 16.88 0.94 1.02 0.20 12.98 8.73 9.17 7.69
Observations 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85
Panel B: Absolute Deviation from Temperature
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres in Population
Absolute Devation from Temperature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) 2.590*** 3.772*** 2.518*** 2.679*** 3.492***
[0.770] [0.974] [0.860] [0.777] [1.046]
Absolute Devation from Temperature in Spring 1792 (1767-1791) -2.647 5.326 4.817
[2.704] [3.215] [3.189]
Absolute Devation from Temperature in Autumn 1792 (1767-1791) 1.511 0.319 1.330
[1.500] [1.283] [1.386]
Absolute Devation from Temperature in Winter 1792 (1767-1791) 0.591 0.827 1.216
[0.589] [0.528] [0.756]
Geographic Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
F-stat (1st stage) 11.32 0.96 1.01 1.01 8.04 5.79 7.03 4.15
Observations 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85
Note: This ta ble reports robus tness checks to our baseline rst-stage speci …cation in the 2SLS regressions where the IV is the squared deviation of
standardized summer temperature in 1792 (Panel A) and the absolute deviation of standardized summer te mperature in 1792 (Panel B) and where the
instrumented variable is the shar e of émigrés in the population (the dependent variable in the second stage of the 2SLS regressio n is GDP per capita in 1860
as shown in Tables 4 and D.12) when all geographic and historical controls are included. The robustness checks consider the e¤ect of the squared and absolute
deviation f rom standardized temperature in spring, fall, and winter 1792. The dependent variable is in logar ithm. Robust standard errors are reported in
brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level.
74
Table D.7: Robustness Checks: Deviations from Temperature in Summer 1792 on GDP per
Capita 1860: Summers 1788-1800
Panel A. GDP per capita 1860
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13)
Reduced Form
GDP per capita 1860
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) -1.572*** -1.485*** -1.551*** -1.510*** -1.775*** -1.651*** -1.656*** -1.085** -1.578*** -2.356*** -1.245** -1.750*** -1.582***
[0.381] [0.373] [0.391] [0.400] [0.518] [0.395] [0.482] [0.450] [0.385] [0.508] [0.514] [0.460] [0.384]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1788 (1763-1787) 0.225
[0.188]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1789 (1764-1788) 0.0267
[0.0576]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1790 (1765-1789) 0.142
[0.115]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1791 (1766-1790) 0.259
[0.415]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1793 (1768-1792) 0.0260
[0.0348]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1794 (1769-1793) 0.0535
[0.146]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1795 (1770-1794) 0.290**
[0.141]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1796 (1771-1795) 0.0855
[0.152]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1797 (1772-1796) 0.316**
[0.156]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1798 (1773-1797) 0.141
[0.171]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1799 (1774-1798) -0.0154
[0.0254]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1800 (1775-1799) -0.0891
[0.210]
Adjusted R2 50.745 48.659 51.532 48.843 53.864 49.995 47.751 56.946 44.806 56.396 49.938 50.004 49.379
F-stat 0.643 0.646 0.638 0.642 0.639 0.640 0.638 0.655 0.639 0.654 0.641 0.639 0.639
Geographical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85
Panel B. GDP per capita 2010
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13)
Reduced Form
GDP per capita 2010
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) 1.093*** 1.077*** 1.151*** 1.141*** 1.123** 0.896*** 1.022** 1.217*** 1.088*** 0.839* 0.812* 0.702* 1.102***
[0.316] [0.328] [0.318] [0.336] [0.440] [0.320] [0.422] [0.365] [0.313] [0.438] [0.463] [0.421] [0.320]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1788 (1763-1787) -0.0406
[0.113]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1789 (1764-1788) 0.0739
[0.0453]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1790 (1765-1789) 0.108
[0.103]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1791 (1766-1790) -0.0386
[0.331]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1793 (1768-1792) 0.0650**
[0.0260]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1794 (1769-1793) 0.0452
[0.121]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1795 (1770-1794) 0.0735
[0.107]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1796 (1771-1795) 0.0709
[0.125]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1797 (1772-1796) 0.102
[0.113]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1798 (1773-1797) -0.120
[0.120]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1799 (1774-1798) -0.0338
[0.0214]
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1800 (1775-1799) 0.0878
[0.112]
Adjusted R2 0.596 0.590 0.601 0.596 0.590 0.618 0.591 0.592 0.591 0.594 0.595 0.602 0.593
Geographical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
F-stat 69.199 64.722 63.743 72.482 68.747 81.521 62.906 68.585 64.497 73.169 62.912 73.857 63.111
Observations 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86
Note: This table reports reduced-form re gressions that assess the e¤ect of the squared deviat ion from
standardized temper ature in the summer of 1792 on GDP per capita in 1860 (Panel A) and GDP per capita
in 2 010 (Panel B), account ing for the squared deviatio n standardized temperature in the summe rs over the
1788-1800 period. It shows t hat only the squared deviation fr om standardized temperature in 1792 has a
negative impact on GDP per capita in 1860 and a positive impact on GDP per capita in 2010. The dependent
variables are in l ogarithm. Robust standard erro rs are re ported in brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% level,
** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level .
75
Table D.8: First-Stage Regressions: Squared and Absolute Deviations from Tempe rature and
Rainfall in Summer 1792
(1) (2) (3) (4)
First stage: the instrumented variable is the Share of E migres
Squared Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) 6.159*** 6.458***
[1.499] [1.524]
Squared Deviation from Rainfall in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) 0.980*
[0.525]
Absolute Deviation from Temperature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) 2.590*** 2.840***
[0.770] [0.828]
Absolute Deviation from Rainfall in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) 0.617
[0.420]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Ye s Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Ye s Yes
F-stat (1st stage) 85 85 85 85
Observations 16.862 28.958 13.190 18.876
Note: This table reports robustness checks to our baseline rst- stage speci …cation in the 2SLS re gressions
where the IV is the squared and absolute deviation of standardized summ er temperature in 1792 and where
the instrumented var iable is the share of émigrés in the population (the dependent vari able in the second
stage of the 2SLS regression is GDP per ca pita in 1860 as shown in Table 3). The robustne ss checks conside r
the e¤ect of the squared and absolute deviation from st andardized rainfall in the summer of 179 2. All the
depende nt variables are in logarithm. Robust standard errors are report ed in brackets. *** signicant at the
1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level.
76
Table D.9: First-Stage Regressions: The Impact of Summer Deviations f rom Temperature in
Summer 1792 on Emigration, Accounting f rom Spatial Correlation
(1) (2) (3)
OLS OLS OLS
Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 4.336 5.950 6.216
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791)
White Robust Standard Errors [1.140]*** [1.445]*** [1.481]***
Spatial std. errors, 25 km [1.038]*** [1.278]*** [1.332]***
Spatial std. errors, 50 km [1.043]*** [1.279]*** [1.333]***
Spatial std. errors, 100 km [1.141]*** [1.278]*** [1.319]***
Spatial std. errors, 200 km [1.449]*** [1.185]*** [1.177]***
Spatial std. errors, 300 km [1.634]*** [1.154]*** [1.102]***
Spatial std. errors, 400 km [1.732]** [1.185]*** [1.071]***
Spatial std. errors, 500 km [1.761]** [1.229]*** [1.069]***
Geographic controls No Yes Yes
Historical controls No No Yes
Observations 86 86 86
Note: This table reports White robust standard errors and spatial Conley (1999) standard errors for the
rst stage of our 2SLS regr essions between our IV, the square d deviation from standardized tempe rature in
the summe r of 1792, and the i nstrumented variable, the share of émigrés in the populat ion. The dependent
variable is in logarithm. Robust standard errors are reported in b rackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% level, **
at the 5% l evel, * at the 10% level.
77
Table D.10: Robustness Checks: Baseline Deviations from Temperature in S umm er 1792 and
GDP p er capita 1860 and 2010
Panel A. GDP per capita 1860
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
Reduced Form
GDP per capita 1860
Squared Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) -1.572***
[0.381]
Absolute Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) -0.637***
[0.167]
Squared Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1742-1791) -1.050***
[0.282]
Absolute Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1742-1791) -0.740***
[0.177]
Squared Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1776-1800) -3.524***
[0.819]
Absolute Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1776-1800) -1.152***
[0.334]
Squared Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1751-1775) -0.614***
[0.183]
Absolute Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1751-1775) -0.618***
[0.153]
Squared Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1751-1800) -1.731***
[0.432]
Absolute Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1751-1800) -0.748***
[0.209]
Adjusted R2 0.643 0.627 0.635 0.638 0.654 0.639 0.623 0.628 0.641 0.629
F-stat 50.745 44.345 41.400 39.224 58.143 49.856 36.158 34.390 45.597 40.144
Geographical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Ye s Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85
Panel B. GDP per capita 2010
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
Reduced Form
GDP per capita 2010
Squared Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) 1.093***
[0.316]
Absolute Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) 0.516***
[0.140]
Squared Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1742-1791) 0.627***
[0.229]
Absolute Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1742-1791) 0.304**
[0.144]
Squared Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1776-1800) 2.439***
[0.632]
Absolute Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1776-1800) 0.951***
[0.209]
Squared Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1751-1775) 0.388***
[0.144]
Absolute Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1751-1775) 0.213*
[0.121]
Squared Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1751-1800) 1.168***
[0.366]
Absolute Devation from Tem perature in Summer 1792 (1751-1800) 0.471***
[0.167]
Adjusted R2 0.596 0.599 0.569 0.544 0.608 0.620 0.564 0.534 0.589 0.569
F-stat 69.199 70.393 74.461 81.776 69.595 74.409 72.049 90.221 72.318 69.639
Geographical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86
Note: This table reports reduced-form regressions that assess the e¤ect of our IVs, the s quared and
abso lute deviations from standardized t emperature in the summer o f 1792, on GDP per capita in 1860 (Panel
A) and GDP per capita in 2010 (Panel B), where we consider ba seline periods other than the 25 ye ars preceding
1792. In all speci…cations, the squared devia tion from standardized temperature in 1792 has a neg ative impact
on GDP per capita in 1860 and a positive impact on GDP per capita in 2010. The dependent variables are
in logarithm. Robust standard errors are reported in bracket s. *** signi…cant at the 1% level, ** at the 5%
level, * at the 10% le vel.
78
Table D.11: Summer Temperature Shock 1792 and Emigration: Falsi…cation Tests
Panel A. Violence before and after 1789-1815.
(1) (2) (3) (4)
OLS OLS OSLS OSLS
Riots during Flour War White Terror - Convictions White Terror - Convictions White Terror
May - June 1775 in Ordinary Court 1815-1816 in Provost Courts 1816-1818 Arrests 1815-1816
Squared Deviation from Temperature -2.807 -6.521 0.870 0.347
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.954] [4.265] [1.883] [2.825]
Geographical Controls Yes Ye s Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 86 84 84 84
Panel B. Cahiers de Doleances.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS OLS
Approving Vote State Intervention Abolition of Mercantilist Reform or Abolition Abolition of Tendency Towards
by Head in Education Guilds Demands of Feudal Dues Serfdom Socialism
Squared Deviation from Temperature 0.764 0.575 0.113 -0.131 0.772 -0.115 -0.106
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [0.632] [0.507] [0.335] [0.346] [0.687] [0.144] [0.214]
Geographical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 77 77 77 77 77 77 77
Panel C. Human Capital before the Revolution.
(1) (2) (3) (4)
OLS OSLS OLS OLS
Share of grooms who Share of brides who Share of grooms who Share of brides who
signed their wedding contract signed their wedding contract signed their wedding contract signed their wedding contract
1686-1690 1686-1690 1786-1790 1786-1790
Squared Deviation from Temperature -0.876 0.101 -0.273 -1.732
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.363] [1.425] [1.521] [1.390]
Geographical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 75 75 78 78
Panel D. Clergy and Aristocracy at the Outbreak of the Revolution
(1) (2) (3)
OLS OLS OLS
Share of Clergymen Against the Number of Noble Families Share of Noble Families in Gotha
1791 Oath to the Civil Constitution of the Clergy in Gotha Almanach 1790 Almanach in Population 1790
Squared Deviation from Temperature -1.434 -19.92 0..00006
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.698] [19.22] [0.00007]
Geographical Controls Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Yes
Observations 76 83 83
Note: This table reports reduced-form r egressions between our IV, the squared deviation from stan-
dardize d temperature in the summer of 1792 and several var iabl es which could potent ially be endogenous to
economic g rowth, and which could bias our estimates if they were correlated with our IV. These are variables
pertaining to violence before 1789 and after 18 15, demands from the cahiers de doléances (Panel B), measures
of human capital before the Revolution (Pa nel C), and measures for the p resenc e of the local clergy and
aristocracy at the outbreak of the Revolution (Panel D). All the dependent variables are in logarithm. Robust
standard errors are reported in brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% leve l, * at the 10% lev el.
79
Table D.12: Emigrés and GDP per capita (IV: Absolute Deviation of Temp erature in Summer 1792)
Panel A. GDP per capita 1860-1930
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)
OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS
GDP per capita 1860 GDP per capita 1901 GDP per capita 1930
Share of Emigres -0.0109 -0.0811*** -0.186** -0.246*** -0.00861 -0.0681 -0.214 -0.278 0.0340 -0.00614 -0.0386 -0.0370
[0.0322] [0.0304] [0.0729] [0.0784] [0.0388] [0.0534] [0.158] [0.193] [0.0289] [0.0288] [0.0535] [0.0459]
Adjusted R2 -0.011 0.585 -0.012 0.278 0.002 0.608
Geographical Controls No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls No No No Yes No No No Yes No No No Yes
Observations 85 85 85 85 83 83 83 83 85 85 85 85
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Absolute Deviation from Temperature 2.612*** 2.590*** 2.163*** 1.937*** 2.612*** 2.590***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [0.708] [0.770] [0.651] [0.641] [0.708] [0.770]
F-stat (1st stage) 13.616 11.320 11.050 9.139 13.616 11.320
Panel B. GDP per capita 1995-2010
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)
OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS OLS OLS 2SLS 2SLS
GDP per capita 1995 GDP per capita 2000 GDP per capita 2010
Share of Emigres 0.0237 0.0478** 0.205*** 0.204*** 0.0238 0.0553** 0.223*** 0.215*** 0.0201 0.0493* 0.195*** 0.197***
[0.0195] [0.0212] [0.0615] [0.0670] [0.0199] [0.0222] [0.0675] [0.0704] [0.0225] [0.0254] [0.0660] [0.0706]
Adjusted R2 0.003 0.472 0.001 0.470 -0.005 0.466
Geographical Controls No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls No No No Yes No No No Yes No No No Yes
Observations 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Absolute Deviation from Temperature 2.632*** 2.620*** 2.632*** 2.653*** 2.632*** 2.620***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [0.701] [0.757] [0.701] [0.739] [0.701] [0.757]
F-stat (1st stage) 14.107 11.970 14.107 12.871 14.107 11.970
Note: This table reports the e¤ect of the share of émigrés in t he population on the logarithm of GDP per
capita in OLS and 2SLS regressions in 1860, 1901, and 1930 (Panel A) and in 1995, 2000, and 20 10 (Panel
B). The IV in the rst sta ge of the 2SLS regressi ons is the absolute standardized deviation from t emperature
in the summ er of 1792. All the dependent variables are in loga rithm. Robust standard e rrors are reported in
brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level.
80
Table D.13: The ect of the Social Categories of Emigrés on GDP per capita in 1860 and 2010
(1) (2) (3) (4)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
GDP per capita 1860 GDP per Capita 2010
Share of Rich Emigres -0.293** 0.205**
(Clergy, Nobility, Upper Middle Class) [0.116] [0.0885]
Share of Poor Emigres -0.0824*** 0.0605**
(Lower Middle Class, Workers, Peasants) [0.0313] [0.0244]
Geographic Controls Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 68 68 69 69
First stage: the instrumented variable is
Share of Rich Emigres Share of Poor Emigres Share of Rich Emigres Share of Poor Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 4.342*** 15.46*** 4.638*** 15.70***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.247] [3.840] [1.293] [3.760]
F-stat (1st stage) 12.130 16.207 12.862 17.422
Note: Thi s table reports the ect of the di¤erent categories of émigrés in the population on GDP per
capita in 1860 and 2010 in 2SLS regressions. All the dependent variables are in logarithm. The IV in the rst
stage of the 2SLS regressions is the squared standardized deviation from temperature in the summer of 1792.
Robust standard errors are reported in brackets. *** signicant at the 1% l evel, ** at the 5% level, * at the
10% level.
81
Table D.14: Emigrés and Population Size, 1801-2010
Panel A. Population of Département, 1801-2010
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Population of Département
1801 1821 1841 1861 1881 1901 1921 1968 1982 1999 2010
Share of Emigres 0.0600 0.0778 0.0975 0.0630 -0.139 -0.0447 0.202 0.398** 0.492** 0.554*** 0.594***
[0.0927] [0.0956] [0.0989] [0.107] [0.148] [0.165] [0.148] [0.182] [0.195] [0.204] [0.208]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 84 84 84 86 84 84 86 86 86 86 86
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.834*** 6.834*** 6.834*** 6.216*** 5.131*** 5.131*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.547] [1.547] [1.547] [1.487] [1.221] [1.221] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487]
F-stat (1st stage) 19.515 19.515 19.515 17.476 17.657 17.657 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476
Panel B. Population of Chef-Lieu of Département, 1806-2006
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Population of Chef-Lieu of Département
1806 1821 1841 1861 1881 1901 1921 1946 1968 1982 1999 2006
Share of Emigres -0.188 -0.0795 -0.186 0.0696 0.143 0.517 0.585 0.700 0.802 0.867* 0.942* 0.972**
[0.273] [0.240] [0.219] [0.270] [0.298] [0.475] [0.508] [0.518] [0.498] [0.491] [0.492] [0.482]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 86 86 84 85 86 86 86 86 86 86 86 86
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.834*** 6.209*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216*** 6.216***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.487] [1.487] [1.547] [1.484] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487] [1.487]
F-stat (1st stage) 17.476 17.476 19.515 17.514 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476 17.476
Note: This table reports the e¤ect of the share of émigrés in the populat ion on the population in each
département (Panel A) and in the chef -lieu (i.e., main administr ative center) of each d épartement over the
1801-2010 period. All the dependent variables are in logarithm. The IV in the rs t stage of the 2SLS regressi ons
is the squared standar dized deviat ion from temperature in the summer of 1792. Robust standard errors are
reported in brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% leve l, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level.
82
Table D.15: Emigrés and Financial Development: Savings Banks’Loans and Contracts Sealed
by Notaries
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Total Value of Loans from Savings Banks Contracts Sealed by Notaries
1875 1881 1900 1861 1901 1931
Share of Emigres -0.122 -0.166 0.0108 -0.197* -0.141 0.167
[0.290] [0.256] [0.195] [0.112] [0.131] [0.133]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 83 83 83 86 83 86
First Stage: the Instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 6.216*** 4.895*** 6.216***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.487] [1.209] [1.487]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.378 16.378 16.378 17.476 16.378 17.476
Reduced Form
Squared Deviation from Temperature -0.600 -0.813 0.0527 -1.225* -0.689 1.039
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.611] [1.430] [1.068] [0.692] [0.702] [0.853]
Note: This table reports the e¤ect of the share o f émigs in the population on the amount o f loans giv en
by savings banks (columns 1-3) and the number of contracts sealed by notaries (columns 4-6) where the IV
is the squared standardized deviation from summer temperature in 1792. All the dependent variables are in
logarithm. Robust standard errors are reported in brackets. *** signicant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level,
* at the 10% level.
83
Table D.16: Emigrés and Civil Servants in the Workforce in th e 19th century
(1) (2) (3)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Share of Civil Servants in Workforce
1851 1866 1881
Share of Emigres 0.814*** 0.363** 0.150
[0.217] [0.180] [0.262]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes
Observations 84 86 83
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.834*** 6.216*** 4.895***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.547] [1.487] [1.209]
F-stat (1st stage) 19.515 17.476 16.378
Note: This table reports the e¤e ct of the share of émigrés in the population on the share of civil servants
in the workforce during the 19th century where the IV is the squared standardized deviation from summ er
temperature in 1792. All the dependent va riables are in logarithm. Robust standard errors are reported in
brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% level, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level.
84
Table D.17: Emigrés and Octroi Tax Rates, 1875
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Share of Communes with Octroi in 1875 Octroi Tax Rates
Out of Total Number of Communes by Département in 1875 on
in Département) Pure Alcohol Beef Sheep Pork
Share of Emigres in Population 1.281*** 0.199 0.261** 0.319* 0.337**
[0.428] [0.248] [0.116] [0.174] [0.164]
Geographical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 83 83 83 83 83
First stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.209]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.378 16.378 16.378 16.378 16.378
Reduced Form
Squared Deviation from Temperature 6.269*** 0.973 1.278** 1.559* 1.650**
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [2.140] [1.351] [0.579] [0.881] [0.812]
Note: This table reports the e ct of the share of émigrés in the population on the share of communes
with an octroi in each département in 1875 as well as on the ta x rates on several goods in 1875 where the
IV is the squared standar dized de viation from summer temperatur e in 1792. All the dependent variables a re
in logarithm. Robust standard errors are reported in brackets. *** signicant at the 1% level, ** at the 5%
level, * at the 10% le vel.
85
Table D.18: Emigrés and Public Spending before World War I
Panel A. Primary schools and male & female population age 5-15
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Ratio of schools to male and female population age 5-15
1876 1881 1886 1891 1896 1901
Share of Emigres -0.387** -0.407** -0.389** -0.335* -0.277 -0.427***
[0.156] [0.167] [0.157] [0.183] [0.187] [0.156]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 83 83 82 82 83 83
First Stage: the instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.893*** 4.811*** 4.895*** 4.895***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.209] [1.209] [1.210] [1.239] [1.209] [1.209]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.378 16.378 16.359 15.065 16.378 16.378
Panel B. Total Public Spending on Education per Pupil in Primary Schools
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Total Public Spending per Pupil
1876 1881 1886 1891 1896 1901
Share of Emigres 0.0005 -0.184* -0.133 -0.393** -0.127 -0.358**
[0.0971] [0.102] [0.0908] [0.165] [0.103] [0.139]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 83 83 83 83 83 83
First Stage: the Instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Devation from Temperature 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.209]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.378 16.378 16.378 16.378 16.378 16.378
Panel C. Roads & Railroads
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS 2SLS
Area Covered by Roads Area Covered by Railroad Total Spending on
within Department’sTerritory within Department’sTerritory Road Maintenance
1881 1900 1913 1881 1900 1913 1881 1900 1913
Share of Emigres -0.526*** -0.447*** -0.671*** -0.443** -0.172 -0.155 -0.153 -0.587*** -0.417***
[0.160] [0.143] [0.225] [0.223] [0.130] [0.117] [0.179] [0.175] [0.134]
Geographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 83 83 83 83 83 83 83 83 83
First Stage: the Instrumented variable is Share of Emigres
Squared Deviation from Temperature 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895*** 4.895***
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.209] [1.209]
F-stat (1st stage) 16.378 16.378 16.378 16.378 16.378 16.378 16.378 16.378 16.378
Note: This table repor ts the e ct of the shar e of émigs in the popula tion on measures per taining to
public spending on education per pupil (Panel A), the number of primary schools with respect to the male
and female population ages 5-15 (Panel C), and the infrastructur e of roads and railroads (Panel C) where the
IV is the squared standar dized de viation from summer temperatur e in 1792. All the dependent variables a re
in logarithm. Robust standard errors are reported in brackets. *** signicant at the 1% level, ** at the 5%
level, * at the 10% le vel.
86
Table D.19: Summer Temperature Shock 1792 and Religiosity before World War I: Falsi…cation
Tests
(1) (2) (3) (4)
OLS OLS OLS OLS
Share of Representatives in the lower House of Parliament Number of Religious Communities Devoted to
Against the Separation of Church & State Educational Purposes 1856 Charity Purposes 1856 Only Religious Purposes 1856
Squared Deviation from Temperature -0.671 -2.419 2.930 -0.254
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [0.534] [2.131] [1.903] [2.467]
Geographical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 83 82 82 82
Note: This table reports reduced- form regr essions between our IV, the square d deviation from standard-
ized temperatur e in the summer of 1792 and variables which could potentially be endogenous to economic
growth, and which could bias our estimates if they we re correlated with our IV. These are variables pertaining
to r eligiosity befor e World War I. All the dependent variables are in logarithm. Robust standard errors are
reported in brackets. *** signi…cant at the 1% leve l, ** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level.
Table D.20: Summer Temperature Shock 1792 and the Phylloxera: Falsi…cation Tests
(1) (2)
OLS OLS
Departments hit by
the Phylloxera in
1875 1890
Squared Deviation from Temperature -0.347 -0.312
in Summer 1792 (1767-1791) [0.735] [1.005]
Geographical Controls Yes Yes
Historical Controls Yes Yes
Observations 86 86
Note: This table reports reduced- form regr essions between our IV, the square d deviation from standard-
ized temperatur e in the summer of 1792 and variables which could potentially be endogenous to economic
growth, and which could bias our estimates if they we re correlated with our IV. These are variables pertaining
to the d éparteme nts hit by the phylloxera in 1875 and 1890. All the dependent variables are in logarithm.
Robust standard errors are reported in brackets. *** signicant at the 1% l evel, ** at the 5% level, * at the
10% level.
87
Table D.21: Descriptive Statistics for Variables in Robustness Analysis
Obs. Mean Std.Dev Min. Max.
Infant Mor tali ty (Age 0-1)
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1811 85 0.30 0.08 0.16 0.53
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1821 85 0.29 0.10 0.14 0.60
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1831 85 0.32 0.09 0.16 0.53
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1841 85 0.27 0.08 0.14 0.46
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1851 85 0.30 0.08 0.16 0.48
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1861 88 0.29 0.10 0.12 0.63
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1871 86 0.31 0.08 0 0.49
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1881 86 0.25 0.08 0 0.48
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1891 86 0.22 0.06 0 0.40
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1901 86 0.19 0.04 0 0.29
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1911 86 0.04 0.01 0.02 0.07
Infant Mortality (Age 0-1) 1931 89 0.07 0.01 0.01 0.10
Coale Fertility Index
Coale Fertility Index 1811 87 0.40 0.10 0.24 0.87
Coale Fertility Index 1821 87 0.39 0.11 0.24 0.82
Coale Fertility Index 1831 87 0.37 0.11 0.23 0.74
Coale Fertility Index 1841 87 0.34 0.08 0.21 0.61
Coale Fertility Index 1851 87 0.34 0.07 0.21 0.54
Coale Fertility Index 1861 90 0.31 0.06 0.21 0.48
Coale Fertility Index 1871 88 0.29 0.06 0.18 0.50
Coale Fertility Index 1881 88 0.29 0.06 0.20 0.57
Coale Fertility Index 1891 88 0.25 0.05 0.16 0.45
Coale Fertility Index 1901 88 0.25 0.04 0.18 0.42
Coale Fertility Index 1911 87 0.21 0.03 0.14 0.30
Coale Fertility Index 1931 90 0.19 0.03 0.12 0.25
88
Table D.22: Descriptive Statistics for Variables in Robustness Analysis
Obs. Mean Std.Dev. Min. Max
Octroi Tax Rates
Octroi Tax Rates Pure Alcohol 1875 86 13.07 7.12 3.8 45
Octroi Tax Rates Oil of First Quality 1875 86 9.50 6.12 0 42.65
Octroi Tax Rates Beef 1875 86 7.62 2.61 3 20
Octroi Tax Rates Veal 1875 86 8.21 3.91 0 20
Octroi Tax Rates Sheep 1875 86 8.27 3.04 0 20
Octroi Tax Rates Pork 1875 86 7.02 3.02 0 20
Octroi Tax Rates Charcoal 1875 86 0.71 1.14 0 10
Cahiers de Doleances
Approving Vote by Head 77 0.06 0.25 0 1
Etatisme in Education 77 0.05 0.28 0 2
Abolition in Guilds 77 0.03 0.16 0 1
Mercantilist Demands 77 0.04 0.19 0 1
Reform or Abolition of Feudal Dues 77 0.08 0.27 0 1
Abolition of Serfdom 77 0.01 0.11 0 1
Tendency towards Socialism 77 0.0 0.1 0 1
Noble Families
Number of Noble Families in Gotha Almanach 1790 85 13.67 7.66 1 41
Share of Noble Families in Gotha Almanach in 1790 Population 83 0.00005 0.000025 0.000003 0.0001
Total Public Spending per Pupil
Total Public Spending per Pupil 1876 86 4.12 10.29 0 93.28
Total Public Spending per Pupil 1881 86 8.35 4.52 0 22.88
Total Public Spending per Pupil 1886 86 18.43 4.97 3.06 37.10
Total Public Spending per Pupil 1891 86 26.70 5.81 16.05 50.17
Total Public Spending per Pupil 1896 86 32.39 7.06 18.92 53.67
Total Public Spending per Pupil 1901 86 39.25 29.79 16.97 302.18
Commune Public Spending per Pupil
Commune Public Spending per P up il 1876 86 12.36 3.76 4.04 29.68
Commune Public Spending per P up il 1881 86 10.27 5.60 2.47 43.19
Commune Public Spending per P up il 1886 86 9.78 12.36 1.57 111.28
Commune Public Spending per P up il 1891 86 8.43 14.31 1.01 128.01
Commune Public Spending per P up il 1896 86 7.12 10.07 1.52 82.45
Commune Public Spending per P up il 1901 86 12.28 15.31 1.16 127.04
Pre-revolutionary human capital
Share of grooms who signed their wedding contract 1686-1690 77 0.26 0.15 0.06 0.64
Share of brides who signed their wedding contract 1686-1690 77 0.12 0.07 0.01 0.33
Share of grooms who signed their wedding contract 1786-1790 80 0.42 0.24 0.05 0.92
Share of brides who signed their wedding contract 1786-1790 80 0.23 0.17 0.02 0.69
Violence before and after the Revolution
Riots during Flour May-June 1775 88 3.50 13.94 0 101
White Terror- Convictions in Ordinary Court 1815-1816 85 44.07 43.69 0 185
White Terror- Convictions in Provost Court 1815-1816 85 3.15 3.92 0 24
White Terror - Arrests 1815-1816 85 39.79 59.32 0 494
Départements hit by Phylloxera
Départements hit by Phylloxera 1875 89 0.18 0.39 0 1
Départements hit by Phylloxera 1890 89 0.29 0.46 0 1
Religiosity before WWI
Number of Religious Communities Devoted to Educational Purposes 1856 85 36.15 167.28 0 1547
Number of Religious Communities Devoted to Charitable Purposes 1856 85 16.69 77.463 0 712
Number of Religious Communities Devoted to Only ReligiousPurposes 1856 85 7.73 36.06 0 333
Share of Representatives in the lower House of Parliament Who Voted against Separation of Church & State 1905 86 0.68 0.30 0 1
89
Table D.23: Descriptive Statistics for Variables in Robustness Analysis
Obs. Mean Std.Dev. Min. Max
Population of Departement
Population of Departement 1801 85 641577.8 2933688 110732 27300000
Population of Departement 1821 86 706318.6 3249226 121418 30500000
Population of Departement 1841 86 793475.5 3651846 132584 34200000
Population of Departement 1861 89 837300.4 3925182 125100 37400000
Population of Departement 1881 87 862890.3 4005441 74244 37700000
Population of Departement 1901 87 892279.3 4150369 92304 3.90E+07
Population of Departement 1921 89 876884.7 4138580 89275 3.92E+07
Population of Departement 1968 88 593623.9 791113.2 80736 6648664
Population of Departement 1992 88 649898 821404.6 76948 6285496
Population of Departement 1999 88 698841.7 878124.3 75644 6340619
Population of Departement 2010 88 747640.3 942826 79096.9 6860285
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 1806 88 28030.7 70275.86 857 649412
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 1821 88 28839.17 71452.48 2792 657172
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 1841 85 38780.45 102935.3 4465 935261
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 1861 87 58251.8 184675.9 5139 1696141
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 1881 88 73552.09 245154.9 6749 2269023
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 1901 88 98459.64 311575.6 7065 2714068
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 1921 88 111380.4 353485.3 6109 2906472
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 1946 88 122694.7 367106 6010 2725374
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 1968 88 158219.7 441138.5 9331 3224442
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 1982 88 154265.8 427001.5 9282 3370085
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 1999 88 155334.1 428480.4 9109 3427738
Population of Chef-Lieu of Departement 2006 88 154276.4 435911.3 8681 3479900
Ratio of schools to male and female population age 5-15
Ratio of schools to male and female population age 5-15 1876 86 0.013 0.005 0.004 0.029
Ratio of schools to male and female population age 5-15 1881 86 0.013 0.006 0.004 0.054
Ratio of schools to male and female population age 5-15 1886 85 0.013 0.004 0.004 0.028
Ratio of schools to male and female population age 5-15 1891 84 0.011 0.004 0.003 0.021
Ratio of schools to male and female population age 5-15 1896 86 0.014 0.006 0.003 0.029
Ratio of schools to male and female population age 5-15 1901 86 0.016 0.006 0.004 0.033
Infrastructure and Spending on Infrastructure
Roads in Departement’s Territory 1881 (in percent) 86 12.53 3.46 5.00 21.20
Roads in Departement’s Territory 1900 (in percent) 86 5.47 1.86 2.34 12.86
Roads in Departement’s Territory 1913 (in percent) 86 12.70 3.53 1.81 20.65
Area Covered by Railroad withiin Departement’s Territory 1881 (in percent) 85 0.62 0.70 0.14 5.97
Area Covered by Railroad withiin Departement’s Territory 1901 (in percent) 85 0.84 0.53 0.25 4.55
Area Covered by Railroad withiin Departement’s Territory 1913 (in percent) 85 1.00 0.65 0.32 5.91
Total Spending on Road Maintenance 1881 86 3101386 1962050 335044 16200000
Total Spending on Road Maintenance 1900 86 1624075 1062873 218520 7595945
Total Spending on Road Maintenance 1912 86 2757364 1466609 353330 8948850
Contracts Sealed by Notaries
Contrats Sealed by Notaries 1861 88 40001.82 18805.45 8644 139690
Contrats Sealed by Notaries 1901 85 31436.32 22222.62 6157 179727
Contrats Sealed by Notaries 1931 88 33577.77 35862.64 4662 306451
Total Value of Loans from Savings Banks
Total Value of Loans from Savings Banks 1875 86 3132973 2964086 300374 18500000
Total Value of Loans from Savings Banks 1881 86 5864920 5311230 716117 37400000
Total Value of Loans from Savings Banks 1900 85 13200000 15800000 2360311 139000000
90