Trinity College Dublin Lecturer: Martin P aredes
Department of Economics Hilary Term 2007
Industrial Organization
Answer Key to A ssignm ent # 3
1. In a linear Hotelling town ther e are 100 potential costumers that are uniformly distributed on a unit
mile. Each consumer has a willingness to pay for pizza of $30, andwouldbuyonlyonepizzaper
week. Itcostaresident$10 per mile to travel. Assume two pizza stores are considering opening
shops on opposite ends of the street. After opening, each store would have a marginal cost of $5 per
pizza, an there is no xed cost for opening a store.
(a) What are the equilibrium prices each store will charge for pizza? What would their prots be?
Each pizza store will charge p = t + c =10+5=15, where t is the transportation cost
and c is the marginal cost. At these prices, the stores would split the market. All customers
would purchase because the farthest any customer has to travel is 0.5 miles, incurring a $5
transportation cost. So, the highest eective price is $20 (because it is p + tx = 15 + 10(0.5)),
w ell below the consumers willingness to pay. Thus q
1
= q
2
=50. So the protperweekforeach
rm would be π
1
= π
2
=(15 5) 50 = $500.
(b) Intuitively, would both stores be happy with their price and location choice, or would one of
them want to change their price/location? In fact, what would happen to the rms’ prices if
they were located right next to each other?
Both rms have an incentive to change their location. Keeping prices xed, if one rm moves
towards the other, it would expand its market share (simply draw the two rms eective prices
before and aft er one of the rms moves to see this). Thus, when both rms change $15 for their
pizzas, neither one is happy with their location. However, the closer and closer rms locate,
the less their products dierentiated, there will be erce price competition. In the limit, if they
are located right next to each other, prices will go do wn to marginal cost (p = c).
(c) Suppose the rms decide to merge (i.e., they become a monopolist). What would the rms
incentive to merge be (assume that the rms would serve the entire market after the merger)?
We need to compare the prots before and after the merger. Before the merger (part (a)),
both rms get π
1
+ π
2
=2 500 = $1000. Let’s calculate now the prots post merger. First,
notice that, if the rms merge, they no longer have to w orry about price competition. Since the
maximum a consumer is willing to pay is $30 and the maximum transportation cost a consumer
will pay is $5 (this is the transportation cost paid by the marginal consumer, located at the
z =
1
2
), then the merged rm can charge $25 and still sell to all the consumers. In this case the
prots per week are Π
M
=(25 5) 100 = $2000
Therefore, before the merger both rms together got π
1
+ π
2
= $1000, and after the merger the
new rm gets Π
M
= $2000. The dierence ($1000) is the total incentive to merge.
2. Cabral, problem 10.1.: First-time subscribers to the Economist pay a lower rate than repeat sub-
scribers. Is this price discrimination? Of what type?
This is an example of third-degree price discrimination. The market is segmen ted in to new subscribers
and repeat subscribers. New subscribers, know the product less well and are thus likely to be more
price sensistive. Moreover, the fact that they have not subscribed in the past indicates that they are
1
likely to be willing to pay less than current subscribers. It is therefore optimal to set a lower price
for new subscribers.
3. Cabral, problem 10.3.: Cement in Belgium is sold at a uniform delivered price thro ughout the country,
that is, the same price is set for each customer, including transportation costs, regardless of where
the customer is located. The same is practice is also found in the sale of plasterboard in the United
Kingdom. Are these cases of price discrimination?
Yes, these are cases of price discrimination. Consider the total price being paid by each customer,
P , as being composed of the price actually charged and the transportation cost; P = p
i
+ t
i
.Since
locations are dierent, transportation costs are dierent, thus, each consumer is charged a price p
i
that depends on his or her location. This is a clear example of geographic price discrimination.
4. Cabral, problem 10.4.: A restaurant in London has recently removed prices from its menu: each
consumer is asked to pay what he or she thinks the meal was worth. Is this a case of price discrimi-
nation?
It is likely that each consumer will pay a price that reects his or her willingness to pay. In that
sense, this is a situation of close to perfect price discrimination.
5. Cabral, problem 10.8.: Coca-Cola recently announced that it is developing a ”smart” vending ma-
chine. Such machines are able to change prices according to the outside temperature. Suppose for
the purposes of this problem that the temperature can be either ”High” or ”Low.” On days of ”High”
temperature, demand is given by Q = 280 2p,whereQ is number of cans of Coke sold during the
day and p is the price per can measured in cents. On days of Low temperature, demand is only
Q = 160 2p. There is an equal number days with High” and ”Low” temperature. The marginal
cost of a c an of Coke is 20 cents.
(a) Suppose that Co ca-Cola indeed installs a ”smart” vending machine, and thus is able to charge
dierent prices for Coke on ”Hot” and ”Cold” days. What price should Coca-Cola charge on a
”Hot” day? What price should Coca-Cola charge on a ”Cold” day?
On a Hot day, Q = 280 2p,orp = 140
1
2
Q. Marginal revenue is MR = 140Q. Equating to
marginal cost (20) and solving, we get Q
= 120 and p
=80. On a Cold day, Q = 160 2p,or
p =80
1
2
Q. Marginal revenue is MR =80 Q. Equating to marginal cost (20) and solving,
we get Q
=60and p
=50.
(b) Alternatively, suppose that Coca-Cola continues to use its normal vending machines, which must
be programmed with a xed price, independent of the weather. Assuming that Coca-Cola is risk
neutral, what is the optimal price for a can of Coke?
Observe from part (a) that even on a Hot day the optimal price is no greater than 80 cents.
So, we can restrict our attention to prices of 80 cents or less. In this price range, the expected
demand is given by Q =0.5(2802p)+0.5(1602p) = 2202p.Solvingforp gives p = 110
1
2
Q.
The marginal revenue associated with this expected demand curve is given by MR = 110 Q.
Equating this marginal revenue to marginal cost, we get Q
=90. and p
=65.
(c) What are Coca-Cola’s prots under constant and weather-variable prices? How much would
Coca-Cola be willing to pay to enable its vending machine to vary prices with the weather, i.e.,
to have a ”smart” vending machine?
2
Under price discrimination, from part (a),prots on a Hot day are (80 20)120 = $72,and
prots on a Cold day are (5020)60 = $18. Expected prots per day are therefore ($72+$18) =
2 = $45. Under uniform pricing, expected prots per day are (65 20)90 = $40.50. It follows
that Coca-Cola should be willing to pay up to an extra $4.50 per da y for a ”smart” vending
machine.
6. A monopolist faces the inverse demand curve P = z (36 Q),whereP is price, Q is total output
and z is the quality og product sold, which can take on only two values. The monopolist can choose to
market a low-quality product for which z =1. Alternatively, the monop olist can choose to market a
high-quality product for which z =2. Marginal cost is independent of quality and is constant at zero.
Fixed, cost, however, depends on the product design and increases with the quality chose. Specically,
xed cost is equal to 65z
2
.
(a) Find the monopolist’s prots if it maximises prots and chooses a low-quality design.
For z =1, prots for this rms are given by:
Π = PQ VC(Q) FC
=(1)(36 Q)(Q) 0 65(1)
2
=36Q Q
2
65
The rst order condition yields:
dΠ
dQ
=36 2Q =0
Q =18
P =36 (18) = 18
Protisthengiveby:
Π = PQ VC(Q) FC
= (18)(18) 65
= 324 65 = 259
(b) Find the monopolist’s prots if it maximises prots and chooses a high-quality design.
For z =2, prots for this rms are given by:
Π = PQ VC(Q) FC
=(2)(36 Q)(Q) 0 65(2)
2
=72Q 2Q
2
260
The rst order condition yields:
dΠ
dQ
=72 4Q =0
Q =18
P =(2)(36 (18)) = 36
3
Protisthengiveby:
Π = PQ VC(Q) FC
= (36)(18) 260
= 648 260 = 388
(c) Comparing your answers to (a) and (b), what quality choice should the monopolist make?
The monopolist will go with high quality.
7. General Foods is a monopolist and knows that its market for Bran Flakes contains two types of
consumers. Type A consumers have indirect utility functions V
A
=20z, whiletypeBconsumers
have indirect utility functions V
B
=10z. In each case, z is a measure of product quality, which can
be chosen from the interval [1, 2]. Ther e are N consumers in the market, of which General Foods
knows that a fraction λ is of type A, and the remainder from typ e B. For simplicity, assume that all
costs are zero.
(a) Suppose that General Foods can tell the dierentconsumertypesapartandsocanchargethem
dierent pric es for the same quality of breakfast cereal. What is the pr ot-maximising strategy
for General Foods?
Since both types have increasing willingness to pay as quality rises, the rm will sell maximum
quality z
A
= z
B
=2to each type. Price to type A consumers is 40 while the price to type B
consumers is 20.
(b) Suppose now that General Foods does not know what type of consumer is which. Show how its
prot-maximising strategy is determined by λ.
From the participation constraint of type B consumers, we get p
B
=10z
B
. From the incentive
compatibility constraint of type A consumers, we get p
A
=20z
A
10z
B
. Then the rm’s total
protisΠ = N [λp
A
+(1 λ) p
B
]=N [20λz
A
+10(1 2λ) z
B
] . It is easy to see that the rm
will set z
A
as high as possible, so z
A
=2. The quality for type B consumers will depend on the
value of λ.
If λ
1
2
(so that there more low-type consumers), then protisincreasinginz
B
. As such,
the rm will set z
B
=2. In other words, General Foods will oer a unique product, of the
highest quality, at price p =20
If λ
1
2
(so that there more high-type consumers), then protisdecreasinginz
B
. As such,
the rm would set z
b
=1.Atthispointtherm even has to decide whether to oer a
low-qualit y good. If the rm only sells the high-quality product, it can set a price as high
as p =40, getting prots Π =40.Iftherm sells both products, then it will charge
apricep
B
=10for the low-quality good, but the highest possible price they can charge
for the high quality good is p
A
=30(in order to satisfy type A’s incentive compatibility
constraint). As a result, prots will be Π = N [30λ +10(1 λ)] = (10 + 20λ) N. Hence,
they will only oer the high quality good.
8. In a two-period economy, one consumer wishes to buy a TV set in period 1. The copnsumer lives for
two periods, and is willing to pay a maximum price of 100 euros per period of TV usage. In period
2, two consumers (who live in period 2 only) are born. each of the newly-born consumers is willing
to pay a maximum of 50 euros for using a TV in period 2. Suppose that in this market there is only
one rm producing TV sets, that TV sets are durable, and that production is costless.
4
(a) Calculate the prices the monopoly charges for TV sets in perios 1 and 2.
We solve for the monopolys prot maximising prices starting from the second period. The
second period outcome may depend on two cases:
First-period consumer does not buy in period 1: Clearly, in this case, the second
period prot maximising price is P
2
=50, yielding a prot level of Π
2
=3× 50 = 150.
First-period consumer buys in period 1: In this case the second period protmax-
imising price is again P
2
=50, yielding a protlevelofΠ
2
=2× 50 = 100.
Altogether, the second-period price is independent of the action of the rst period buyer in the
rst period. Therefore, the maxim um price the monopoly can c harge the rst-period buyer in
the rst period is P
1
= 150.
(b) An swer the previous question assuming that in the rst period a consumer who lives two periods
is willing to pay no more than 20 euros per period for TV usage.
The second period outcome may depend on two cases:
First-period consumer does not buy in period 1: In this case, the monopoly has two
choices: (i) charging P
2
=20, and sell to all three consumers, thereby earning a second
period protofΠ
2
=3× 20 = 60; or, (ii) charging P
2
=50, and selling only to the second
period consumers, thereby earning a second period protofΠ
2
=2× 50 = 100.
First-period consumer buys in period 1: In this case the second period protmax-
imising price is again P
2
=50, yielding a protlevelofΠ
2
=2× 50 = 100.
Altogether, the second period price is independent of the actions of the rst period buyer.
Now, in order to attract the rst-period buy er to purchase in period 1, the monopoly should
set P
1
=40, thereby extracting all surplus from all consumers.
9. Cabral, problem 15.2.: In less than one year after the deregulation of the German telecommunications
market at the start of 1998, domestic long-distance rates have fallen by more than 70%. Deutsche
Telekom, the former monopolist, accompanied some of these rate drops by increases in monthly fees
and local calls. MobilCom, one of the main competitors, fears it may be unable to match the price
reductions. Following the announcement of a price reduction by Deutche Telekom at the end of 1998,
shares of MobilCom fell by 7%. Two other competitors, O.tel.o and Mannesmann Arcor, said they
would match the price cuts. VIAG Interkom, however, accused Telekom of ”competition-distorting
behavior,” claiming the company is exploiting its (still remaining) monopoly power in the local market
to subsidize its long-distance business. Is this a case of predatory pricing? Present arguments in favor
and against such assertion.
One could indeed argue that this is a case of predatory pricing. If Deutsche Telekon has monopoly
in local markets, it likely has nancial resouces strong enough to aord losing money in the long
distance market by pricing below marginal cost. However, since there are two other competitors that
matched Deutsche Telekom’s prices, one can argue that there exists technology with marginal cost
less than the low-price charged. Evidently, other explanations can also invoked, namely low-cost
signaling and reputation for toughness.
10. Cabral, problem 15.3.: ”The combined output of two merging rms decreases as a result of the
merger.” True or false?
If the merger implies little or no cost eciencies (namely at the level of marginal cost), we w ould
expect the combined output of the merging rms to decline. If however the merger reduces the
5
marginal cost of the combined rm signicantly, then it is possible that the combined output increases
as a result of the merger.
11. Kikkoman is the dominant supplier in the market of say sauce, but it faces continuous entry threats.
Suppose that Kikkoman incurs a cost C(q
1
)=6q
1
. Kikkoman faces potential entry by Red Zen, which
produces a perfect substitute for Kikkoman’s product. However, Red Zen’s production costs are given
by C(q
2
) = 100 + 12q
2
, so that MC
2
=12. The demand for soy sauce is given by D(P ) = 120 P.
(a) Suppose initially that the incumbent, Kikkoman, can credibly commit to produce some output,
after which Red Zen will choose its own output
i. Find Red Zen’s best response function
Red Zen’s prot function is π
2
= P · q
2
C(q
2
) = (120 q
1
q
2
)q
2
100 12q
2
. Marginal
revenue is MR
2
= 120 q
1
2q
2
, while marginal cost is MC
2
=12. Since MR
2
= MC
2
,
we obtain the entrant’s best response function:
q
2
= BR(q
1
)=54
1
2
q
1
.
ii. If Kikkoman accommodates entry, nd the incumbent’s prot-maximizing quantity and its
resulting prots.
Kikkoman will act as a Stackelberg leader and will ch oose its quantity knowing what Red
Zen’s best response will be. Thus, Kikkoman’s eective demand is P = 120 q
1
q
2
=
120 q
1
¡
54
1
2
q
1
¢
=66
1
2
q
1
, so marginal revenue is MR
1
=66 q
1
, while marginal
cost is MC
1
=6. This gives q
1
=60,makingprots π
1
= 1800
(b) Alternatively, the incumbent can attempt to deter entry by engaging in “limit pricing”. In fact,
it would set a quantity so that the entrant will not be able to make a prot.
i. Show that q
1
=88is the quantity that results in the limit price, and nd that price and the
incumbent’s associated prot.
Since Kikkoman knows Red Zen’s best response function, it can nd the quantity that will
make Red Zen achieve zero prots. Red Zen’s prots are π
2
= (120q
1
q
2
)q
2
10012q
2
.
Substituing q
2
=54
1
2
q
1
into π
2
, we get:
π
2
=
µ
108 q
1
µ
54
1
2
q
1
¶¶µ
54
1
2
q
1
100 = 0
This reduces to
¡
54
1
2
q
1
¢
2
= 100 q
1
=88.
When q
1
=88, Red Zen is indierent between entry and non-entry, so q
2
=0. Then,
P = 120 88 = 32 and π
1
=(32 6)88 = 2288.
ii. Will the incumbent prefer to deter entry or accommodate entry?. Explain.
The incumbent will prefer to deter entry. By limit pricing, Kikkoman receives higher prots
with detering entry (π
1
= 2288) than by acommodating entry (π
1
= 1800).
12. Consider a Cournot industry c omposed of 3 rms, facing a demand D(P ) = 150 P. Initially,
the three rms are identical and have the same marginal cost $ 30. As such, the Cournot-Nash
equilibrium is for each rm to produce 30 units at a price of $60. Suppose that two of those rms
decide to merge, and that, as a result, the merged rm will realize a savings in its variable cost. In
other words, post-merger marginal cost would be equal to $ c<30.
6
(a) Calculate the post-merger equilibrium output level of the merged rm and the non-merged rm,
and compute the corresp onding price and prots.
Now we have an asymmetric Cournot duopoly. Without loss of generality, suppose rm 1 & 2
merge. The best response function for the merged rm is:
q
m
=
150 c
2
q
3
2
The other rm’s best response function is:
q
3
=
150 30
2
q
m
2
=60
q
m
2
Solving we get:
q
m
=
150 c
2
1
2
³
60
q
m
2
´
q
m
=60
2
3
c
and
q
3
=30+
1
3
c
Then, P = 150
¡
60
2
3
c
¢
¡
30 +
1
3
c
¢
=60+
1
3
c.Prots for the merged rm are π
m
=
¡
60 +
1
3
c c
¢¡
60
2
3
c
¢
=
¡
60
2
3
c
¢
2
= 3600 80c +
4
9
c
2
and prots for the nonmerged rm
are π
3
=
¡
60 +
1
3
c 30
¢¡
30 +
1
3
c
¢
=
¡
30 +
1
3
c
¢
2
= 900 + 20c +
1
9
c
2
.
(b) Compare your results in p art (a) with the (pre-merger) Cournot-Nash equilibrium and deter-
mine:
i. How large should the savings be for the merger to be protable?
The merger is protable if
π
m
π
1
+ π
2
.
3600 80c +
4
9
c
2
2(900)
1800 80c +
4
9
c
2
0
Solving, we get c 90 45
2 26.3. In other words, the new marginal cost has to reduce
up to aproximately c =26in order for the merger to be protableforthemergerrms.
ii. How large should the savings be for the merger to benetconsumers?
The merger will benet consumers if
P
m
P
60 +
1
3
c 60
It is very easy to see that the merger will never benetconsumers
7