Trinity College Dublin Lecturer: Martin P aredes
Department of Economics Hilary Term 2007
Industrial Organization
Answer Key to A ssignm ent # 2
1. Consider the following games in normal form. For each game:
i. Determine whether the game can be solved by dominant strategies
ii. Determine all Nash equilibria in pure strategies.
(a)
L R
T 2, 5 3, 2
B 1, 2 4, 3
i. No, the game cannot be solved by dominant strategies.
ii. There are two Nash equilibria: (B,R), (T,L)
(b)
L R
T 10, 10 5, 5
B 5, 5 1, 1
i. No, the game cannot be solved by dominant strategies.
ii. There are t wo Nash equilibria: (B,L), (T,R)
(c)
L C R
T 100, 100 0, 0 50, 200
M 0, 0 1, 1 0, 0
B 0, 300 0, 0 200, 200
i. No, the game cannot be solved by dominant strategies.
ii. There is one Nash equilibrium: (M,C)
(d)
L C R
T 10, 4 1, 5 98, 4
M 9, 9 0, 3 99, 8
B 1, 98 0, 100 100, 98
i. No, the game cannot be solved by dominant strategies.
ii. There is one Nash equilibrium: (T,C)
1
2. Find the Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium outcomes and payos of the following games:
(a)
U
D
2
D
(2,0)
(0,2)
U
U
D
2
1
(0,2)
(2,0)
X
X
There are two subgame perfect Nash equilibia (SPNE)
(b)
U
U
D
1
D
(8,8)
(2,1)
U
U
D
D
1
1
2
2
(1,1)
(6,6)
U
D
1
D
(0,5)
(2,2)
U
U
D
1
2
(2,2)
(1,1)
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
The unique SPNE of the game calls for player 1 to play Up, then player 2 plays Up and nally
pla yer 1 one plays Up. Both players get a payo of 8.
3. Cabral, problem 4.2.: The UK Oce of Fair Trading has recently unveiled a plan that will oer
immunity from prosecution to rms who blow the whistle on their co-cartel c onspirators. In the U.S.,
this tactic has proven extremely succ e ssful: since its introduction in 1993, the total amount of nes
for anti-competitive behavior has increased twentyfold. Show how the tactic initiated by the U.S.
DepartmentofJusticeandsoontobefollowedbytheOce of Fair Trading changes the rules of the
game played between rms in a secret cartel.
Prior to the introduction of the plan, each cartel rm would have two options: (a) to stick by the
agreement or (b) to deviate and set lower prices. With the introduction of the plan, the rm has
2
a third option: (c) to blow the whistle. Let α be the probability that the DOJ discovers the price
conspiracy. High values of α imply a low expected value from (a). The same is true of (b), though
probably to a lesser extent. Finally, (c) is invariant to the value of α. We would thus expect that,
for high values of α, (c) is the best strategy.
With the introduction of the plan, the rms now play a second prisoner’s dilemma type of game.
Before, it was whether to price high or price low. Now, it’s whether to blow the whistle or not. Firm
would be better o if neither of them blew the whistle. However, if α is high, blowing the whistle is
a dominat strategy.
4. Cabral, problem 4.5.: Hernan Cortez, the Spanish navigator and explorer, is said to have burnt his
ships upon arrival to Mexico. By so doing, he eectively eliminated the option of him and his soldiers
returning to their homeland. Discuss the strategic value of this action knowing the Spanish colonists
were faced with potential resistanc e from the Mexican natives.
By eliminating the option of turning back, Hernan Cortez established a credible commitment re-
garding his future actions, that is, to ght the Mexican natives should they attack. Had Cortez not
made this mov e, natives could have found it better to attack, knowing that instead of bearing losses
the Spaniards would prefer to withdraw.
5. Cabral, problem 4.6.: Consider the following game depicting the process of standard setting in high-
denition television (HDTV). The U.S. and Japan must simultaneously decide whether to invest a
high or a low value into HDTV research. Each country’s payoo are summarized in Figure 3.
(a) Are ther e any dominant strategies in this game? What is the Nash equilibrium of the game?
What ar e the r ationality assumptions implicit in this equilibrium?
For the United States investing, a low value in HDTV research is a dominant strategy. The
Nash equilibrium of the game is given by the U.S. choosing Low and Japan choosing High.
The rationality assumptions implicit in this solution are that both players are rational and,
moreover, Japan belives the U.S. acts rationally.
(b) Suppose now the U.S. has the option of committing to a strategy ahead of Japan’s decision. How
would you model this new situation? What are the Nash equilibria of this new game?
See Figure 3. (See also Section 4.2.) By solving bac kwards, with get the following Nash
equilibrium: U.S. chooses High, Japan chooses Low.
(c) Comparing the answers to (a) and (b), what can you say about the value of commitment for the
U.S.?
Comparing the answers from (a).and(b). we can see that the value of commitment to the U.S.
is1thatis,3minus2.
3
(d) ”When pre-commitment has a strate gic value, the player that makes that commitment ends up
‘regretting’ its actions, in the sense that, given the rivals’ choices, it could achieve a higher
payo by choosing a di
R
°
erent action.” In light of your answer to (b), how would you c omment
this statement?
Given that Japan chooses Low, the U.S. would be better o by choosing Low as w ell. However,
it m u st be the case that the cost of switching from High to Lo w is so high that the U.S. won’t
do it (ex post). Otherwise, the commitmen t to stick to High would not be credible.
6. Cabral, problem 7.1.: According to Bertrand’s theory, price competition drives rms’ prots down to
zero even if there are only two competitors in the market. Why don’t we observe this in practic e very
often?
Section 7.2 suggests three possible explanations: (a) product dierentiation, (b) dynamic competi-
tion, (c) capacity constraints.
7. Cabral, problem 7.2.: Three criticisms are frequently raised against the use of the Cournot oligopoly
model: (i) rms normally choose prices, not quantities; (ii) rms don’t normally take their decisions
simultaneously; (iii) rms are frequently ignorant of their rivals’ costs; in fact, they do not use the
notion of Nash equilibrium when making their strategic decisions. How would you respond to these
criticisms?
(i) If rms are capacity constraint, then price competition \looks like” like quatitiy competition. See
Section 7.2.
(ii) If there are signicant information lags, then sequential decisions ”look like” sim u ltaneous deci-
sions. See Chapter 4 (\rst section).
(iii) The last section of Chapter 7 presents an argument for the relevance of Nash equilibrium which
only requires each rm to know its own prot function.
8. Suppose there ar e two rms. IT&T and Horizon, that are the only two cellular providers in Fargo,
ND. Both rms act as Cournot competitors and face the (inverse) demand function P (Q)=A BQ,
where Q = q
1
+ q
2
. Assume that each rm has constant marginal costs equal to c.
(a) Find an expression for IT&T’s output as a best response function to the output of rm 2. Find
the analogous expression for Horizon. Graph the two reaction functions.
P (Q)=A B(q
1
+ q
2
),thenMR
1
= A Bq
2
2Bq
1
. By equating MR
1
= c,weget
q
1
=
A Bq
2
c
2B
Analogously,
q
2
=
A Bq
1
c
2B
4
q
2
q
1
(A-c)/B
(A-c)/2B
Firm 1’s best response function
(A-c)/2B
(A-c)/B
Firm 2’s best response function
N
q*
1
q*
2
(b) Find an expression for each rm’s equilibrium output and the equilibrium price.
Using the best response functions, we substitute one into the other to get the equilibrium
outputs. For rm 2,
q
2
=
A Bq
1
c
2B
=
A B
³
ABq
2
c
2B
´
c
2B
q
2
=
A c
3B
Likewise,
q
1
=
A c
3B
Recalling that P (Q)=A B( q
1
+ q
2
), then
P
= A B
µ
2
µ
A c
3B
¶¶
=
A +2c
3
9. Consider a market for a homogeneous product with demand given by Q =37.5
P
4
. There are two
rms, A and B, each with constant marginal cost equal to 54.
(a) Determine output and price under a Cournot equilibrium
P (Q) = 150 4(q
1
+ q
2
),thenMR
a
= 150 4q
b
8q
a
. By equating MR
a
= MC =54,weget
q
a
=12
1
2
q
b
Analogously,
q
b
=12
1
2
q
a
5
Using both reaction curves, we substitute one into the other to get the equilibrium outputs.
For rm A,
q
a
=12
1
2
q
b
=12
1
2
µ
12
1
2
q
a
q
a
=8
Likewise,
q
b
=8
Recalling that P (Q) = 150 4(q
a
+ q
b
), then
P
= 150 4(8+8)=86
(b) Suppose that rm A has a rst-mover advantage. Determine output and price under a Stackel-
berg equilibrium. Explain your results.
Solving using backward induction, rm B’s reaction curve is again:
q
b
=12
1
2
q
a
Firm A internalizes rm B’s reaction curve in to its demand, to nd its (inverse) eective demand,
q
e
a
= Q q
b
.NoticethatQ =37.5
1
4
P.Then
q
e
a
=
µ
37.5
1
4
P
µ
12
1
2
q
e
a
q
e
a
=25.5
1
4
P +
1
2
q
e
a
1
4
P =25.5
1
2
q
e
a
P = 102 2q
1
Then, the eective marginal revenue for rm 1 is MR
1
= 102 4q
1
. By equating MR
1
= MC,
we get:
102 4q
1
=54
q
1
=12
Replacing q
1
=12into rm 2’s reaction curve:
q
2
=12
1
2
(12) = 6
Recalling that P (Q) = 150 4(q
1
+ q
2
), then
P
= 150 4 (12 + 6) = 78
6
10. The following table contains sales gures for three hypothetical industries in the year 2002.
Firm Industry 1 Industry 2 Industry 3
A $300 $1000 $400
B $300 $100 $300
C $300 $60 $300
D $300 $40 $300
E $300 $30 $300
All Others 10 × $50 22 × $35 4 × $100
Figuresinmillionsofcurrentdollars
(a) Compute the 4-rm concentration ratio ( C
4
) for each industry. According to this index, which
industry is most concentrated?
The 4-rm concentration ratio is the sum of the top four rms’ market shares. The market
share is given by dividing the rm’s sales by the total industry sales. In the above table, each
industry has total sales of $2000. The following table giv es the market shares:
Firm Industry 1 Industry 2 Industry 3
A 15% 50% 20%
B 15% 5% 15%
C 15% 3% 15%
D 15% 2% 15%
E 15% 1.5% 15%
All Others 10 × 2.5% each 22 × 1.75% each 4 × 5% each
Thus,wegetthefollowingresultsforC
4
:
Industry 1 Industry 2 Industry 3
Sum of top four market shares $1200 $1200 $1300
C
4
60% 60% 65%
AccordingtotheC
4
, industry 3 would be the most concentrated.
(b) Compute the Herndahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) for each industry. According to this index,
which industry is most concentrated?
To compute the HHI, we sum the squared market share of every rm in a given industry.
For industry 1: HHI=5 (15)
2
+10 (2.5)
2
= 1187. 5
For industry 2: HHI=1 (50)
2
+1 (5)
2
+1 (3)
2
+1 (2)
2
+1 (1.5)
2
+22 (175)
2
= 2607. 6
For industry 3: HHI=1 (20)
2
+4 (15)
2
+4 (5)
2
= 1004.0
Here, industry 2 would be the most concen trated.
(c) Why do you think HHI does a better job than C
4
of measuring industry concentration? Give
tworeasonsforyouranswerandmakesureyourefertotheabovetable.
i. HHI does a better job because it can describe the concen tration of an industry within
the top four rms, whereas CR
4
cannot mak e this distinction. For example, from the
abo ve table, both industry 1 and industry 2 have the same 4-rm concentration ration, yet
industry 2 has one rm with half of the industry’s total sales. In this sense, HHI does a
better job showing that industry 2 is more concentrated that industry 1.
7
ii. On a similar note, HHI does a better job because it can describe the industry beyond just
the top four rms. The HHI index gives a stronger prediction that industry 3 is more
concentrated than industry 1 than CR
4
does. Notice that the HHI for industry 3 is over
15% greater than the HHI for industry 1, whereas the CR
4
for industry 3 is less than 10%
greater than industry 1’s ratio.
(d) Which industry would y ou consider most concentrated? Why?
Industry 2 would appear to be most concen trated since it has one very large rm and all other
rms are small.
11. Cabral, problem 12.1: Consider a duopoly where horizontal pr oduct dierentiation is important.
Firms rst simultaneously choose their product locations, then simultaneously set prices in an innite
series of periods. Suppose that rms collude in prices in the second stage and anticipate this at
the product-positioning stage. What do you expect this implies in terms of the degree of product
dierentiation?
Assuming that both rms are identical, and that there is no punishment regarding the choice of
location, then both rms will locate righ t in the middle, so that there is no product dierentiation
between them.
12. In the Bertrand-Hotelling duopoly, if rms have the same costs but occupy dierent loc ations, the
Nash equilibrium prices are directly related to how dierentiated are the products of the two rms.
Explain
True: With xed locations on a Hotelling line, our index of dierentiation is the transportation cost.
If the transportation cost is very large, then it would take a huge price dierence for customers
”located” near one product to go for the other product (i.e. the products are very dierentiated).
On the other hand, if the transportation cost is very small, it only takes a small price dierence
for customers to get higher net utility from a product located very far away (i.e. the products are
undierentiated). We have found that in the our linear model, the mark-up o ver cost was exactly the
transportation cost. Thus, the more the products are dierentiated, the higher equilibrium prices
are.
8