University of North Carolina School of Law University of North Carolina School of Law
Carolina Law Scholarship Repository Carolina Law Scholarship Repository
Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship
2020
The Death of Custom: Winners and Losers in the Legal The Death of Custom: Winners and Losers in the Legal
Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
Thomas A. Kelley III
University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill
Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.unc.edu/faculty_publications
Part of the Law Commons
Publication:
Syracuse Journal of International Law and Commerce
This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Carolina Law Scholarship
Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of Carolina
Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected].
Volume 47 No. 1
SYRACUSE JOURNAL
OF INTERNATIONAL LAW
AND COMMERCE
SYRACUSE UNIVERSITY COLLEGE OF LAW
The Death of Custom: Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban
Land in Niger
Thomas A. Kelley
Pages 57-109
Cite as: 46 SYRACUSE J. INTL L. & COM. ISSN 0093-0709
The Syracuse Journal of International Law and Commerce is owned, published and printed bi-annually by Syracuse University,
Syracuse, New York 13244-1030, U.S.A. The Journal is one of the oldest student-produced international law journals in the
United States and celebrated forty years of student-production in the Spring of 2013. Editorial and business offices are located at:
Syracuse University College of Law, Dineen Hall, 950 Irving Avenue, Suite No. 346, Syracuse, New York 13244-6070 U.S.A.
The Syracuse Journal of International Law and Commerce actively seeks and accepts article submissions from scholars and
practitioners in the field of public and private international law. The Journal, on occasion, holds international law symposia and
publishes the papers presented therein in addition to its bi-annual volume of submissions.
Issue subscription rates, payable in advance, are: United States, $25.00; foreign, $30.00. Subscriptions are automatically renewed
unless a request for discontinuance is received. Back issues may be obtained from William S. Hein & Co., Inc., 2350 North
Forest Road, Getzville, N.Y. 14068. To ensure prompt delivery, notification should be received one month in advance.
The views expressed are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Syracuse Journal of
International Law and Commerce, its advisors, editors or staff, Syracuse University College of Law or Syracuse University.
Member of National Conference of Law Reviews Member of National Conference of International Law Journals
The Syracuse Journal of International Law and Commerce is indexed in the Index of Legal Periodicals & Books, Current Law
and Legal Resources Index. Full text of selected articles is available on Westlaw® (database SYRJILC).
Copyright © 2020 Syracuse Journal of International Law and Commerce. All rights reserved.
For more information, please visit
http://www.law.syr.edu/students/publications/sjilc/index.asp
 
JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL LAW AND COMMERCE
2019-2020 Editorial Board
Editor-in-Chief
JEANINE CRYAN
Managing Editor
Executive Editor
JUSTIN SANTABARBARA LYDIA PARENTEAU
Notes & Comments
Editors
Form & Accuracy
Editors
Lead Articles
Editors
NICHOLAS CARTER ASHLEY BRUSH STEPHANIE DARAND
DELANEY MOORE MADISON KENYON
RICHARD PADO
CORY POPLAWSKI
ZACHARIA SONALLAH
JU-JUANNA PERKINS
Administrative Editor Business Editor Media Editor
DAVIDA HAWKES CHITRA DAVE NATALIE MAIER
Third-Year Associate
Editors
ALEX TRUNFIO
Second-Year Associate
Editors
MARIAH ALMONTE SHANNON BAUSINGER AUDREY BIMBI
CONOR BOWERS MONEEKA BRAR BRIT BROUILLARD
GREGORY BROWNE ALEXANDRA CALHOUN BRIANA CLAYTON
IMANI DEAS ELENA DELELLA GABRIEL DIAZ
AUDREY FICK JAKE GELLERSTEIN SARAH HANSEN
MAX HUBSCHER KENNETH KNIGHT CODY LIND
CLEE MALFITANO GRACE MANDRY BRENNA MASON
SHARON OTASOWIE TROY PARKER NIMESA PERERA
FRANCES RIVERA REYES KARA ROCKEY
Editorial Staff
ISAAC SIGNORELLI
Faculty Advisor
CHRISTIAN DAY
OFFICERS OF THE UNIVERSITY
Kent D. Syverud, Chancellor and President
Zhanjiang “John” Liu, Interim Vice Chancellor and Provost
COLLEGE OF LAW ADMINISTRATION
Craig M. Boise, B.A., J.D., LL.M. Taxation, Dean and Professor of Law
Keith J. Bybee, A.B., M.A., Ph.D., Vice Dean; Paul E. and Honorable Joanne F. Alper ’72 Judiciary Studies Professor; Professor of Law; Professor of
Political Science; Director, Institute for the Study of the Judiciary, Politics, and the Media; Senior Research Associate, Campbell Public Affairs
Institute
Lauryn P. Gouldin, A.B., J.D., Associate Dean for Faculty Research; Associate Professor of Law
Deborah Kenn, B.A., J.D., Associate Dean of Clinical and Experiential Education; Bond, Schoeneck & King Distinguished Professor; Professor of Law;
Director, Office of Clinical Legal Education
Kathleen M. O'Connor, A.B., J.D., Associate Dean of Online Education; Teaching Professor
Sophie Dagenais, D.E.C., B.C.L., LL.B., Assistant Dean for Advancement and External Affairs
Heidi Hart-Gorman, B.A., M.B.A., M.S.W., Assistant Dean for Finance and Administration
Andrew S. Horsfall, B.A., J.D., Assistant Dean of International Programs
J. Zachary Kelley, B.S., M.S., Assistant Dean for Student Resouces and Internal Research
Denée Page, B.A., J.D., Assistant Dean of Enrollment Management
FACULTY
Rakesh K. Anand, A.B., J.D., Professor of Law
Robert Ashford, B.A., J.D., Professor of Law
Elizabeth A. August, B.A., J.D., Teaching Professor
James E. Baker, B.A., J.D., Professor of Law; Director, Institute for Security Policy and Law; Professor of Public Administration, Maxwell School of
Citizenship and Public Affairs (by courtesy appointment)
Kristen Barnes, A.B., J.D., Ph.D., Professor of Law
Peter A. Bell, B.A., J.D., Professor of Law
Todd A. Berger, B.A., J.D., LL.M., Associate Professor of Law; Director, Advocacy Programs
Peter D. Blanck, B.A., Ph.D., J.D., University Professor; Chairman, Burton Blatt Institute
Craig M. Boise, B.A., J.D., LL.M. Taxation, Dean and Professor of Law
Jennifer S. Breen, B.A., M.A., Ph.D., J.D., Associate Professor of Law
Emily Brown, B.A., J.D., Assistant Teaching Professor
Keith J. Bybee, A.B., M.A., Ph.D., Vice Dean; Paul E. and Honorable Joanne F. Alper ’72 Judiciary Studies Professor; Professor of Law; Professor of
Political Science; Director, Institute for the Study of the Judiciary, Politics, and the Media; Senior Research Associate, Campbell Public Affairs
Institute
Sanjay K. Chhablani, B.A., J.D., Laura J. & L. Douglas Meredith Professor of Teaching Excellence; Professor of Law; Professor, Forensic and National
Security Sciences Institute, College of Arts and Sciences (by courtesy appointment)
Bruce Ching, B.A., M.A., J.D., Senior Faculty Fellow
Kelly K. Curtis, B.A., J.D., Teaching Professor
Christian C. Day, A.B., J.D., Professor of Law
Lisa A. Dolak, B.S., J.D., Senior Vice President and University Secretary; Angela S. Cooney Professor of Law
Doron Dorfman, B.A., LL.B., LL.M., J.S.M., J.S.D., Associate Professor of Law
David M. Driesen, B.Mus., M.Mus., J.D., University Professor
Jan Fleckenstein, B.A., M.L.S., M.S./IRM, J.D., Associate Teaching Professor; Director of the Law Library
Ian Gallacher, B.A., M.F.A., J.D., Professor of Law; Director, Legal Communication and Research
Shannon P. Gardner, B.A., J.D., Teaching Professor
Gregory L. Germain, B.A., J.D., LL.M., Professor of Law; Director, Bankruptcy Clinic
Shubha Ghosh, B.A., Ph.D., J.D., Crandall Melvin Professor of Law; Director, Syracuse Intellectual Property Law Institute
Antonio Gidi, LL.B., LL.M., Ph.D., S.J.D., Teaching Professor
Lauryn P. Gouldin, A.B., J.D., Associate Dean for Faculty Research; Associate Professor of Law
Andrew S. Greenberg, B.A., J.D., Teaching Professor
Margaret M. Harding, B.A., J.D., Professor of Law
Laurie Hobart, B.A., J.D., M.F.A., Assistant Teaching Professor
Paula C. Johnson, B.A., J.D., LL.M., Professor of Law; Co-Director, Cold Case Justice Initiative
Arlene S. Kanter, B.A., J.D., LL.M., Laura J. & L. Douglas Meredith Professor for Teaching Excellence; Professor of Law; Director, COL Disability Law
and Policy Program; Faculty Director of International Programs; Professor of Disability Studies, School of Education (by courtesy appointment)
Gary T. Kelder, B.A., J.D., LL.M., Professor of Law
Deborah Kenn, B.A., J.D., Associate Dean of Clinical and Experiential Education; Bond, Schoeneck & King Distinguished Professor; Professor of Law;
Director, Office of Clinical Legal Education
Andrew Kim, B.A., J.D., Associate Professor of Law
Nina A. Kohn, A.B., J.D., David M. Levy L’48 Professor of Law; Faculty Director of Online Education
Beth G. Kubala, B.S., J.D., LL.M., Teaching Professor; Executive Director of the Wohl Family Veterans Legal Clinic
Laura G. Lape, A.B., M.A., J.D., Associate Professor of Law
Kevin Noble Maillard, B.A., M.A., J.D, Ph.D., Professor of Law
Robin Paul Malloy, B.S., J.D., LL.M., Ernest I. White Chair and Distinguished Professor of Law; Kauffman Professor of Entrepreneurship and
Innovation; Director, Center on Property, Citizenship, and Social Entrepreneurism; Professor of Economics, Maxwell School of Citizenship and
Public Affairs (by courtesy appointment)
Mary Helen McNeal, A.B, J.D., Professor of Law; Director, Elder and Health Law Clinic; Co-Director, London-Ex
Suzette M. Meléndez, B.A., J.D., Teaching Professor; Director, Children's Rights and Family Law Clinic; Director, Syracuse Medical-Legal Partnership;
Faculty Director of Inclusion Initiatives
Aliza M. Milner, B.S., J.D., Teaching Professor
Jessica R. Murray, B.A., J.D., Associate Teaching Professor; Director, Transactional Law Clinic
Robert B. Murrett, B.A., M.S., M.A., Deputy Director, Institute for Security Policy and Law; Professor of Practice, Maxwell School of Citizenship and
Public Affairs
Robert G. Nassau, B.A., J.D., Teaching Professor; Associate Director, Office of Clinical Legal Education; Director, Low Income Taxpayer Clinic
Kathleen M. O'Connor, A.B., J.D., Associate Dean of Online Education; Teaching Professor
Deborah S. O’Malley, B.A., J.D., Associate Teaching Professor
Keli Perrin, B.S., M.P.A., J.D., Associate Teaching Professor; Managing Director, Institute for Security Policy and Law
Gary J. Pieples, B.A., J.D., Teaching Professor; Director, Criminal Defense Clinic
LaVonda N. Reed, B.A., J.D., Associate Provost for Faculty Affairs; Professor of Law
Richard S. Risman, B.A., J.D., Teaching Professor
M. Jack Rudnick, B.A., J.D., Professor of Practice; Director, Innovation Law Center
Michael A. Schwartz, B.A., M.A., J.D., LL.M., Ph.D., Associate Professor of Law; Director, Disability Rights Clinic
William C. Snyder, A.B., J.D., Teaching Professor
Danielle Stokes, B.A., J.D., Faculty Fellow
Kent D. Syverud, B.A., J.D., M.A., Chancellor and President
Mary Szto, B.A., M.A., J.D., Teaching Professor
Erik R. Teifke, B.A., J.D., Professor of Practice, Criminal Defense Clinic
C. Cora True-Frost, B.A., J.D., M.P.A., LL.M., Associate Professor of Law
Terry L. Turnipseed, B.S., M.S., M.S., J.D., LL.M., Professor of Law; Faculty Director of Externship Programs; Professor of Engineering and Computer
Science, L.C. Smith College of Engineering and Computer Science (by courtesy appointment)
A. Joseph Warburton, A.B., M.G.A., J.D., M.S., Ph.D., Professor of Law and Finance
Corri Zoli, B.A., M.A., Ph.D., Associate Teaching Professor; Director of Research, Institute for Security Policy and Law
FACULTY EMERITI
Hannah R. Arterian, B.A., J.D., Dean Emerita
William C. Banks, B.A., M.S., J.D., Professor of Law Emeritus
Leslie Bender, B.A., J.D., LL.M., Professor of Law Emerita
Richard A. Ellison, B.B.A., LL.B., Professor of Law Emeritus
Thomas R. French, B.A., M.L.S., M.A., J.D., Professor of Law Emeritus
Martin L. Fried, B.A., J.D., LL.M., Crandall Melvin Professor of Estates and Trusts Emeritus
Peter E. Herzog, A.B., LL.B., LL.M., Crandall Melvin Professor of Law Emeritus
Hilary K. Josephs, A.B., J.D., Ph.D., Dean’s Distinguished Research Scholar of Asian Law Emerita
Travis H.D. Lewin, B.A., LL.B., S.J.D., Professor of Law Emeritus
Thomas J. Maroney, B.A., LL.B., Professor of Law Emeritus
Janis L. McDonald, B.A., J.D., LL.M., Professor of Law Emerita
Robert J. Rabin, A.B., LL.B., LL.M., Professor of Law Emeritus
Sarah H. Ramsey, B.A., M.A., J.D., LL.M., Laura J. & L. Douglas Meredith Professor for Teaching Excellence; Professor of Law Emerita
Steven S. Wechsler, B.S., M.B.A., J.D., Professor of Law Emeritus
William M. Wiecek, B.A., LL.B., Ph.D., Chester Adgate Congdon Professor of Public Law and Legislation Emeritus
* Thomas A. Kelley is the James Dickson Phillips, Jr. Distinguished Professor of Law and Director of the
University of North Carolina School of Law Institute for Innovation. Professor Kelley earned a B.A. from
Harvard University and a J.D. from Northeastern University School of Law. Before attending law school,
Professor Kelley served as a United States Peace Corps volunteer in the Republic of Niger. After law school,
Professor Kelley clerked for James Dickson Phillips on the 4th Circuit Court of Appeals.
The Death of Custom: Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land
in Niger
Thomas A. Kelley*
I. Introduction
II. About Niger
III. Existing Customary Land Law in Niger
A. The Customary Law Archetype
B. Complicating the Picture of Customary Law
1. The Influence of Colonialism
2. The Influence of Islam
3. The Influence of Economic Liberalization
4. The influence of Government Decentralization
5. Summary
IV. The Death of Customary Law in Peri-Urban Niger
A. History of Land in Niamey and Environs
B. Decentralization Struggles Lead to Chaos in Urban and Peri-Urban Land
Management
C. Enter the Private Developers
D. The Current Situation
E. Summary
V. Winners and Losers when Peri-Urban Land is Transformed from Customary to
Formal
A. Winners
1. Private Real Estate Developers and Investors and the Government
Officials with Whom They Collaborate
B. Losers
1. Intermediate Losers: Secondary Rights Holders
2. Long-Term Losers
a. Those Who Depend on Customary Land for Livelihoods
b. Those Who Define Themselves, Their Communities, Their
History, and Their Religion with Reference to Land
VI. Conclusion
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
58
I.
Introduction
The population of Niamey, the capital city of the West African Republic of Niger, is
exploding.
1
Since urban residents need houses, large tracts of peri-urban
2
land around the city
are being transformed from fields to suburbs.
3
This land transformation is being accompanied
by a legal transformation from customary to formal state law.
4
As is true of most legal
transformations, this one is producing winners and losers.
5
The winners are those with access to
financial, political, and social capital who use their superior strength to take advantage of the
new rules.
6
The losers are the peasant farmers and their families who are uprooted from their
traditions and their main sources of livelihood.
7
Under customary law in rural Niger, land is inextricably interwoven with history, identity,
and religion.
8
One’s access to land depends on membership and good standing in a family, a
1
Hamadou Issaka, La Promotion Immoblière Informelle a Niamey: L’Irregularite Comme Reponse a la Crise du
Logement, URBANITES (Nov. 8, 2013), available at http://www.revue-urbanites.fr/la-promotion-immobiliere-
informelle-a- niamey-lirregularite-comme-reponse-a-la-crise-du-logement/ (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) (arguing
Niamey has undergone vertiginous growth); see The World Factbook (Niger) (People and Society), U.S. CENT.
INTELLIGENCE AGENCY, available at https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ng.html
(last visited Sept. 27, 2019) (estimating Niger's rate of urbanization as 4.27% for 2015-2020, ranking 11th for
highest urbanization rate in the world).
2
There is no universally accepted definition of the term peri-urban. Beacon Mbiba & Marie Huchzeremey,
Contentious Development: Peri-Urban Studies in Sub-Saharan Africa, PROGRESS IN DEV. STUD. 113, 114 (2002).
However, it generally refers to land around the periphery of urban areas that includes elements of both rural and
urban use and where farmland is being converted to suburbs. See Achamyeleh Gashu Adam, Land Tenure in the
Changing Peri-Urban Areas of Ethiopia: The Case of Bahir Dar City, INTL J. OF URB. & REGIONAL RES. 1970,
1970- 1971 (2014) (arguing peri-urban lands are places just outside municipal boundaries where urban and rural
coexist and where farmland is being converted to suburban house plots); Janine Ubink, Traditional Authority
Revisited: Popular Perceptions of Chiefs and Chieftaincy in Peri-Urban Ghana, J. LEGAL PLURALISM &
UNOFFICIAL L. 123, 129 (2007) (defining peri-urban as “approximating a continuum from rural to urban”); See
also IGNASIO MALIZANI JIMU, EVERYDAY PRACTICES AND RELATIONS IN PERI-URBAN BLANTYRE, MALAWAI 69
(2012) (arguing peri-urban land is usually characterized by “the encroachment of the expanding urban area onto the
surrounding rural land . . . affecting the livelihood of small farmers” and where land goes from rural to urban and
from customary to statutory tenure).
3
See infra Part IV.D
4
See JIMU, supra note 2, at 69.
5
See infra notes 276-78 and accompanying text (arguing elites in developing countries always benefit from changes in
the law).
6
See infra Part V.A.
7
See infra Part V.B.
8
See Thomas Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets into Pigeon Holes: The Effects of Globalization and State Legal Reform in
Niger on Indigenous Zarma Law, 34 N.Y.U. J. INTL. L. & POL.635, 680-691 (2002) (arguing land in Nigerien villages
is closely connected to spiritual beliefs, history, and community identity); see see also PARKER SHIPTON, MORTGAGING
59
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
lineage group, and a village.
9
At the same time, land helps define those institutions.
10
Villagers
explain themselves, their family histories, and the linkages between families by recounting
stories of ancestors who founded their villages, usually by clearing the land for agricultural
use.
11
All males who descend from the original, land-clearing ancestors can claim membership
in the lineage and thus present-day access to land.
12
Rural land in Niger is also intertwined with spiritual beliefs. Land helps bind together the
temporal and spiritual worlds.
13
Villages are surrounded by all manner of spirits including the
black spirits (gangi bi) who controlled the land before humans arrived, and the spirits of
ancestors who made pacts with the gangi bi that permitted them to inhabit and exploit the land.
14
Those spirits intervene in the daily lives of rural people, sometimes helping them, sometimes
harming them.
15
Rural Nigerien people who lose their land as a result of urbanization lose their
connections to these powerful practical and symbolic touchstones that bring order and meaning
to their lives, but that is not all they lose. Because most rural Nigeriens rely on subsistence
farming, many will also lose their livelihoods.
16
In Niger, there is no equivalent of Detroit or
THE ANCESTORS: IDEOLOGIES OF ATTACHMENT IN AFRICA 117 (2009) (arguing land is tightly tied up with social
position and also with “the most intimate, emotionally charged dimensions of personhood and pride”).
9
Thomas Kelley, Unintended Consequences of Legal Westernization in Niger: Harming Contemporary Slaves by
Reconceptualizing Property, 56 AM. J. COMP. L. 999, 1006-07; Parker Shipton & Mitzi Goheen, Understanding
African Land-Holding: Power, Wealth, and Meaning, 62 AFR. J. OF THE INTL AFR. INST. 307, 307 (1992) (arguing
land in Africa helps “define personal and social identities”); see SHIPTON, supra note 8, at 110 (arguing in East
Africa, people belong to their land).
10
See Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 663 (describing a Nigerien village that traces its history to a group of
brothers who dug a well and cleared the bush around it).
11
Id.
12
Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1006-08.
13
See id. at 1007 (arguing Nigerien traditional leaders ensure land is used in ways approved by the spirits).
14
See infra note 71 and accompanying text.
15
Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 647-48; Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 107.
16
The World Factbook (Niger) (People and Society), U.S. CENT. INTELLIGENCE AGENCY , available at
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ng.html (last visited Sept. 27, 2019); see U.N. Exec.
Bd. of the U. N. Dev. Programme, the U. N. Population Fund and the U. N. Off. for Project Servs., Country
Programme Document for Niger (2019-2021), ¶ 14, U.N. Doc. GEN/N18/393/74/N1839374 (Nov. 21, 2018) (arguing
that a large part of the Nigereian population is dependent on subsistence farming).
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
60
Pittsburg where displaced agricultural workers can find wage labor,
17
so many will simply
starve.
18
This paper explores Niger’s peri-urban transition in land use and law. Part II provides
background on Niger with an emphasis on the demographics that explain why the country is
facing a potentially cataclysmic if slow-moving land crisis. Part III will indulge in a step often
skipped by legal scholars and development practitioners: it will explore in some detail the
customary law that governs land use in rural areas. Without understanding customary law, one
cannot understand the enormity of the loss that will result when fields become suburbs. Part IV
will shift the lens to the city and describe the legal and political context that has permitted
Niamey’s explosive and largely unregulated growth. It notes that when formal state law and
customary law bump into one another in peri-urban areas, formal law almost always prevails: the
land is irrevocably transformed from a key element of a social, historical, and spiritual complex,
into a commodity. Part V describes in detail who wins and who loses as a result of the
transformation. The paper concludes that the wealthy and well-connected win, while peasant
farmers lose. They lose their livelihoods and, just as important, the customary law that has
sustained their communities through centuries of adversity.
II.
About Niger
Niger is among the poorest, least developed countries in the world.
19
One reason is its
17
See Interview with Hamdallaye Canton Chief, in Hamdallaye, Republic of Niger (May 1, 2018) (arguing “[i]f
peasant farmers sell their land, what will they do? It’s not as if there are factories in the city where they can go find
jobs”); see also SHIPTON, supra note 8, at 33 (arguing that in the U.S. urban employment cushioned the blow from
rural land dispossession but that in Africa no such safety net exists).
18
See infra Part V.B.2.a (describing the livelihood effects of rural Nigeriens losing access to agricultural land).
19
Human Development Reports: Human Development Data (1990-2017), U.N. DEVELOPMENT PROGRAM, available at
http://hdr.undp.org/en/data (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) (ranking Niger as the poorest country in the world out of all 189
countries listed); The World Factbook (Niger) (Introduction), U.S. CENT. INTELLIGENCE AGENCY , available at
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ng.html (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) ("Niger is one of
the poorest countries in the world with minimal government services and insufficient funds to develop its resource
base, and is ranked last in the world on the United Nations Development Programme’s Human Development Index.").
61
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
paucity of natural resources.
20
It is landlocked and two-thirds of its surface is located in the
parched Sahara Desert,
21
a zone unsuitable for agricultural production.
22
The southern third of
the country, where most of the population lives,
23
is only marginally more fecund.
24
The soils
there tend to be sandy and of poor quality,
25
watercourses are rare, and rainfall, upon which most
farmers depend,
26
is sparse and variable.
27
These challenging geographic and climatic realities
are troubling in a country where most peoples’ livelihood depends on agriculture.
28
20
Although Niger’s land is unproductive, it is not completely bereft of natural resources. The World Factbook (Niger)
(Geography), U.S. CENT. INTELLIGENCE AGENCY, available at https://www.cia.gov/ library/publications/the-world-
factbook/geos/ng.html (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) (listing Niger's natural resources as uranium, coal, iron ore, tin,
phosphates, gold, molybdenum, gypsum, salt, and petroleum). It has significant uranium deposits in its northern
mountains, the proceeds of which led to a minor economic boom in the 1970s. Ursula Meyer, Negocier l’acces, la
propriete et l’autorité publique en marge de la ville. Enjeux foncier a Niamey et production d’Etat au Niger 108 (2016)
(doctoral thesis presented to the Faculty of Geosciences and the Environment, Universitiy of Lausanne) (on file with
author). But uranium prices dropped in the 1980s as nuclear power fell out of favor in the developed world, and the
mines have done little to lift Niger out of poverty. Gabriella Korling, In Search of the State, An Ethnography of Public
Service Provision in Urban Niger 58 (2011) (doctoral dissertation in Cultural Anthropology, Uppsala Universitet in
Sweden) (arguing uranium prices fell in the late 1970s). More recently, petroleum deposits have been identified in
northeastern Niger. The World Factbook (Niger), supra note 1; Meyer, supra note 20, at 120 (referring to a recent
increase in mining and oil extraction).
21
U.N. Int'l Human Rights Instruments, Common Core Document Forming Part of the Reports of States Parties: the
Niger, ¶ 1, U.N. Doc. GEN/G18/075/27/G1807527 (May 22, 2018) ("Located in the eastern part of western Africa, the
Niger is a landlocked country with a surface area of 1,267,000 km
2
. Two thirds of the national territory is in the
Saharan zone."); The World Factbook (Niger) (Geography), U.S. CENT. INTELLIGENCE AGENCY, available at
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ng.html (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) ("[L]andlocked;
one of the hottest countries in the world; northern four-fifths is desert, southern one-fifth is savanna, suitable for
livestock and limited agriculture[.]"); Meyer, supra note 20, at 91.
22
Common Core, supra note 21, ¶ 1.
23
The World Factbook (Niger) (Geography), U.S. CENT. INTELLIGENCE AGENCY, available at
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ng.html (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) ("[M]ajority of
the populace is located in the southernmost extreme of the country along the border with Nigeria and Benin[.]");
Meyer, supra note 20, at 91 (arguing 80% of Niger’s population lives in the southern third of the country).
24
The World Factbook (Niger) (Geography), U.S. CENT. INTELLIGENCE AGENCY, available at
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ng.html (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) (reporting that
only 12.3% of Niger's land is "arable").
25
Irahimn Yahaya Ibrahim, Niger in the Face of the Sahelo-Saharan Islamic Insurgency: Precarious Stability in a
Troubled Neighborhood5 (Sahel Research Group, Working Paper No. 004, 2014).
26
The World Factbook (Niger) (Geography), U.S. CENT. INTELLIGENCE AGENCY, available at
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ng.html (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) (reporting that
Niger has only 300km of waterways, ranking 93 out of 107 countries listed); Florence Bron-Saidatou, La Gouvernance
Fonciere au Niger: Malgre des Acquis, de Nombreuses Difficultes 6 (2015) (working paper produced by a coalition of
French Development Agencies).
27
Bron-Saidatou, supra note 26, at 6; see Ambe J. Njoh, The Role and Goals of the State in Urban Development in
Niger, 30 HABITAT INT’L 540, 545 (2006) (referring to Niger’s “low rainfall”).
28
The World Factbook: Africa (Niger), U.S. CENT. INTELLIGENCE AGENCY, available at
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ng.html (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) (arguing that
agriculture provides a livelihood for more than 80% of Niger's population).
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
62
Approximately 85% of Niger’s population engages in agricultural work and most people
depend, at least in part, on subsistence farming for their food.
29
Irrigation is rare, so rainfed
agriculture is vital to peoples’ survival; however, climate change is resulting in a shrinking of
Niger’s rainy season, cutting further into agricultural productivity.
30
Due to decreasing yields,
most households supplement their livelihood by engaging in animal husbandry,
31
wage labor, and
informal small business activity.
32
Niger’s deteriorating agricultural conditions are particularly alarming when one considers
how many mouths there are to feed. The country’s population growth rate is the highest in the
world at 3.9%.
33
In the early 1960s, around the time of Niger’s independence from France, Niger
had approximately 4.3 million inhabitants.
34
By 2012, the population had expanded to 17
million.
35
Estimates put the current population at over 20 million
36
and, if the growth trends
continue, 33 million by 2030.
37
The converging trends of land degradation and population growth means that many
more people, almost all of whom need arable land to feed themselves, must crowd onto ever-
29
The World Factbook (Niger) (People and Society), U.S. CENT. INTELLIGENCE AGENCY, available at
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ng.html (last visited Sept. 27, 2019); see
Country Programme, supra note 16 (arguing that a large part of the Nigereian population is dependent on
subsistence farming).
30
The World Factbook: Africa (Niger), supra note 29 (arguing that rainfall in Niger is declining); Bron-Saidatou,
supra note 26, at 8.
31
Bron-Saidatou, supra note 26, at 6 (arguing 43.2% of Niger’s population engages in animal husbandry).
32
See The World Bank, Republic of Niger Priorities for Ending Poverty and Boosting Shared Prosperity Systematic
Country Diagnostic, 12, Report No. 115661-NE (Nov. 28, 2017).
33
The World Factbook: Africa (Niger), supra, note 29 ("Niger has the highest total fertility rate (TFR) of any
country in the world, averaging close to 7 children per woman in 2016."); Exec. Bd. of the U. N. Dev. Programme,
the U. N. Population Fund and the U. N. Off. for Project Servs., U.N. Population Fund Country Programme
Document for Niger, ¶ 1, U.N. Doc. DP/FPA/CPD/NER/9 (Nov. 27, 2018) ("Niger’s annual demographic growth rate
is the highest in the world, at 3.9 per cent; its population, currently 17,138,707, will double every 18 years."); The
World Bank, supra note 32, at ¶ 52 (arguing at present, an average Nigerien woman experiences 7.3 live births
during her lifetime).
34
Bron-Saidatou, supra note 26, at 4.
35
Id.
36
Niger, THE WORLD BANK, available at https://data.worldbank.org/country/niger?view=chart (last visited Sept. 27,
2019) (reporting Niger's population as 21,602,472 in 2017); Country Programme, supra note 16, ¶ 1 (estimating
Niger's population at 21,466,862 as of 2017).
37
See The World Bank, supra note 36.
63
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
smaller fields upon which less and less rain is falling.
38
The overcrowding, in turn, exacerbates
problems with soil fertility. As the expanding population seeks to feed itself by planting ever-
more staple crops, the amount of fallow land decreases, further diminishing the fields’
productive capacity.
39
The end result is that contemporary Niger experiences periodic acute
food crises and 16.7% of children under the age of 5 are chronically malnourished.
40
Rapid, poorly planned and poorly regulated urbanization is exacerbating the crisis in
rural land and livelihoods.
41
Although Niger is still a predominantly rural society, its rate of
urbanization is among the highest in the world.
42
The challenging demographic and climatic
conditions described in preceding paragraphs are driving the rural population –particularly
young men
43
– towards the city.
44
Further, the lure of the city has been enhanced by the rise of
economic liberalization and structural adjustment policies, which have compelled the Nigerien
state to withdraw much of its healthcare, education, and infrastructure investment from rural
areas.
45
Combined, these factors have led to sizzling growth in Niamey’s population.
46
38
The World Factbook: Africa (Niger), supra note 29; see also Interview with Niamey, Former Resident of Goudel,
in Republic of Niger (Apr. 30, 2018) (arguing the shrinking rainy season will no longer support the best strains of
millet, Niger’s staple crop).
39
Country Programme, supra note 16, ¶ 5 ("Niger’s challenges also result from population pressure, the adverse
effects of climate change, inadequate agricultural practices and resulting land degradation."); Bron-Saidatou, supra
note 26, at 8 (arguing population pressure is leading to shorter fallow periods and the overall degradation of soils);
Interview with Niamey, Judge, Republic of Niger (May 9, 2018) (arguing that due to population pressure it is no longer
possible to let land lie fallow so that it is overcultivated); see generally Hamdallaye, supra note 17 (arguing there is
“enormous pressure on land” in Niger).
40
The World Bank, supra note 32, ¶ 152 ("[B]eing malnourished is almost normal (44 percent of children [are]
stunted)[.]"); see Ibrahim, supra note 25, at 5 (arguing acute malnutrition touches 16.7% of Inger’s children under
5).
41
Meyer, supra note 20, at 90 (arguing rural land loss is causing Nigeriens to seek refuge in cities); see infra notes
259-260 and accompanying text (arguing urban expansion in Niger is guided by private interests and poorly regulated).
42
See The World Factbook (Niger) (People and Society), U.S. CENT. INTELLIGENCE AGENCY, available at
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ng.html (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) (estimating
Niger's rate of urbanization as 4.27% for 2015-2020, which ranks 11th for highest urbanization rate in the world).
43
See THE WORLD BANK, REPUBLIC OF NIGER: PRIORITIES FOR ENDING POVERTY AND BOOSTING SHARED
PROSPERITY: SYSTEMATIC COUNTRY DIAGNOSTIC 40 (Report No. 115661-NE) (2017).
44
Issaka, supra note 1 (arguing thousands of rural citizens seek a better life in Niamey every year and most have no
qualifications); Meyer, supra note 20, at 103, 105 (arguing Niger sees spikes in urban population growth at times of
famine).
45
Meyer, note 20, at 110; see Körling, supra note 20, at 21 (arguing Niamey is privileged over rural areas in both
health and education).
46
Issaka, supra note 1.
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
64
Specifically, in 1977, the capital counted 243,000 residents; by 2000, the number was 650,000;
today, estimates run as high as 1.5 million.
47
Because all of these new arrivals need shelter, and
because most residential construction in Niger is in the form of one-story,
48
metal-roofed, mud
and cement houses surrounded by small walled compounds,
49
the city is gobbling up large
swaths of agricultural land each year and irreversibly converting it into suburban house plots.
50
In sum, Niger is in the midst of a vicious cycle. Due largely to demographic and climatic
pressures on agricultural land, ever more people are seeking sustenance in the city. As the city
grows, it devours the agricultural land that is the main source of food – even if an increasingly
feeble one – for Nigeriens who remain in rural communities. As the following sections will
demonstrate, when real estate developers and investors convert fields to suburbs, rural people
lose not only their source of food but their way of life: a social and spiritual identity that is
rooted in, and to large extent defined by, land.
III.
Existing Customary
Land Law in Rural Niger
51
Customary land law has been remarkably resilient in Niger.
52
In spite of numerous attempts
by Niger’s government during the 20
th
and 21
st
centuries to weaken or eliminate it,
53
most of
47
rling supra note 20, at 77; Common Core, supra note 21, Table 1 (reporting Niamey's population as 397,437 in
1988, 725,030 in 2001, and 1,011,277 in 2012); see The World Factbook: Africa (Niger), supra note 29 (estimating
Niamey's population at 1.214 million in 2018).
48
See Henri Kokou Motcho, Urbanisation et Role de la Chefferie Traditionnelle dans la Communaute Urbaine de
Niamey, 229 LES CAHIERS D’OUTRE-MER, REVUE DE GEOGRAPHIE DE BORDEAUX 73, 74 (2005) (arguing that
Niamey’s expansion has included few multi-story buildings).
49
See id. at 2 (arguing housing density is low in Niamey because most structures are single-story).
50
See infra notes 271-72 and accompanying text.
51
Custom in Africa is a contested and controversial construct. Scholars generally reject the idea that custom was a
static, self-contained body of pristine norms that existed in pre-colonial times. Sara Berry, Privatization and the
Politics of Belonging in West Africa, in LAND AND THE POLITICS OF BELONGING IN WEST AFRICA 241, 245
(Richard Kuba & Carola Lentz eds., 2013). Instead, they view custom as endlessly dynamic and in recent centuries
developed “through interactions between colonial officials and their subjects, each drawing selectively on historical
precedents to influence one another and make the best of changing circumstances.” Id. Colonial governments made
attempts to define, and at times manipulate, custom in ways that supported the state’s authority. Squeezing Parakeets,
supra note 8, at 652-55. But colonial and post-colonial states rarely succeeded in inventing custom from whole cloth
and “have often exercised little real control of it.” Shipton & Goheen, supra note 9, at 308.
52
See Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 656-57; Thomas Kelley, Apples to Oranges: Epistemological Dissonance
in the Human Rights Case Hadijatou Mani v. Niger, 32 QUINNIPIAC U. L. REV. 311, 336-37 (2014).
53
See Bron-Saidatou, supra note 26, at 11-12 (arguing the Nigerien state passed several laws intended to limit
traditional leaders’ authority over land); Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 658, n. 105-06 (arguing Niger’s post-
independence government passed laws aimed and curbing chiefs’ authority over land, all to little effect).
65
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
Niger’s rural land is still governed by it.
54
From the perspective of a western-trained lawyer it can
be diffuse and confusing,
55
but it must be grappled with if one is to understand the profound legal,
social, and spiritual transformation the country is undergoing as urban areas encroach on farm
land. The following discussion will introduce a somewhat idealized, archetypal version of
customary land law before showing how it has been affected by colonialism, the rise of orthodox
Islam, and the pervading influence of globalization and economic liberalism.
A.
The Customary Law Archetype
Descriptions of customary land law in Niger tend toward static, archetypal accounts
56
when in fact it is dynamic, variable, and often messy.
57
Still, the archetype is one that rural
Nigeriens recount, sometimes wistfully, when discussing their communities’ historic relationship
to land.
58
Thus, even if it does not provide a perfectly accurate history of customary land law, it
reveals much about rural peoples’ collective memory and values concerning land.
59
In rural Nigerien villages, the most enduring and powerful land rights are those of first-
comers.
60
Every village has a founding story, often involving brothers or male cousins who left
54
Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 659-60 (arguing most rural people in Niger base land claims on custom and
often have no knowledge and no desire to know what formal state law would say about the matter).
55
Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1008.
56
See Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 653 (arguing the French colonialists in Niger attempted to explain
customary law in terms of fixed rules).
57
See Janine M. Ubink, Tenure Security: Wishful Policy Thinking or Reality? A Case from Peri-Urban Ghana, 51 J.
Afr. L. 215, 231 (2007) (arguing customary law in Ghana is “fluid, relational and negotiable” and “constantly
recreated and disputed); SHIPTON, supra note 8, at 230 (arguing Kenyan customary land law is endlessly dynamic);
Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1006 (referring to Niger’s land use customs as “evolving, fluid, and
negotiable”).
58
Interview with Village Chief in Gassangourni, Republic of Niger (May 18, 2000) and Interview with Yaye Issa and
Issafou Lali (May 22, 1996); Interview with Group of Villagers (ne 1, 1996); Interview with Group of Villagers in
Fandou-Berri, Republic of Niger (May 17, 2000 (morning)).
59
See id.
60
Richard Kuba, Spiritual Hierarchies and Unholy Alliances: Competing Earth Priests in a Context of Migration in
Southwestern Burkina Faso, in LAND AND THE POLITICS OF BELONGING IN WEST AFRICA 57, 60 (Richard Kuba &
Carola Lentz eds., 2006) (arguing in a West African context that land rights arise from first-comers who made pacts
with local deities); Sten Hagberg, Money, Ritual and the Politics of Belonging in Land Transactions in Western
Burkina Faso, in LAND AND THE POLITICS OF BELONGING IN WEST AFRICA 99, 103 (Richard Kuba & Carola Lentz
eds., 2006) (referring to the oldest male descendant establishing land rights by forming an original pact with the
spirits); Meyer, supra note 20, at 125 (arguing Niger’s land law is based largely on “rights of the first to clear”).
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
66
their natal village in search of adventure or due to a rift within their lineage.
61
In some accounts,
the men began by capturing slaves and forcing them to dig a well.
62
The well became the
symbolic and practical center of the new village.
63
Starting from the circumference of the well,
the founders traced pie-shaped lots of land that stretched indefinitely into the surrounding
bush.
64
Nobody paid close attention to the claims’ outer boundaries because land was an
inexhaustible resource.
65
Over time, men would solidify their claims to land by clearing the
bush and tilling the soil.
66
Although there seem not to have been hard and fast rules on the
matter, leaving the land untouched for too long could weaken a claim of access.
67
A father could generally expect that the land he controlled would pass to his sons since
inheritance passed through the male line.
68
The family land would never be formally divided,
but each son would be apportioned a parcel that he would control until he divided it among his
own sons.
69
The lineage head, the village chief, the land chief (laabukoy), and the heads of
families within the lineage would decide how the parcels of land would be divided among young
men.
70
The first-comers formed alliances with the original black spirits (gangi bi) who inhabited
61
See Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 663 (describing the village of Fandou Berri’s founding by a famous
warrior and his brothers who captured slaves and compelled them to dig a well to sustain the village);
62
Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 663 (describing the village of Fandou Berri’s founding by a warrior and his
brothers who captured slaves and compelled them to dig a well to sustain the village); Unintended Consequences,
supra note 9, at 1027 (describing a similar story regarding the village of Saabu Dey).
63
JEAN-PIERRE OLIVIER DE SARDAN, LES SOCIETES SONGHAY-ZARMA (NIGER-MALI) 663 (1984)
(describing the symbolic importance of well digging in Nigerien culture).
64
Interview with Saabu Dey village chief and group of elders, in Saabu Dey, Republic of Niger (December 5, 2003).A
somewhat different version of founders’ land rights, one I have heard only once, involves founders galloping on
horseback, throwing spears into the earth, and vying to knock one another off if there was a disagreement about
boundaries. Interview with Former Resident of Goudel (April 30, 2018). Interview with Niamey, supra note 38.
65
See Meyer, supra note 20, at 125 (arguing agricultural land in Niger was historically abundant and “if a man had
reason he could simply clear land and benefit from its fruits”)
66
Id.
67
Kelley, supra note 9, at 1007; Kelley, supra note 8, at 682, n. 176.
68
Kelley, supra note 8, at 683.
69
Kelley, supra note 8, at 681, n. 175. Typically, young males would work in their father’s fields, and would not be
assigned a separate plot until they married.
70
Kelley, supra note 9, at 1007.
67
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
the bush, and those alliances had to be nurtured and respected by subsequent generations.
71
Because the spirit world, like the temporal world, was dynamic and ever changing,
72
other
actors also came to inhabit the spiritual realm, including the spirits of villagers’ ancestors.
73
If
the spirits were pleased, villagers in the temporal world would prosper in their daily lives.
74
The
rains would fall gently and persistently, while locusts and other pestilence would stay away. If
the spirits were displeased, villagers would suffer crop failure, sickness, and death.
75
Some members of the community were particularly skillful at understanding and
addressing the spirits’ demands.
76
The land chief, often the same person as the village chief,
would ensure that villagers’ use of land would not cause offense.
77
In instances where the spirits
had been offended, the community could organize a spirit possession ceremony to communicate
directly between the realms.
78
During these ceremonies, spirits would inhabit the bodies of
certain villagers and speak directly to the gathered throng.
79
Other villagers, referred to as
zimas, were skilled at summoning the spirits to the temporal world to visit punishments and
rewards upon living people or, conversely, to protect threatened humans from harm.
80
Chiefs in Niger historically played – and still play – important roles in determining access
71
See Kelley, supra note 8, at 646.
72
See id.
73
See id, at 646-47.
74
See id; see also Amadou supra note 61, at 9 (arguing villagers in a Nigerien river village, Karey Kopto, appeal to
the spirits to ensure good fishing, good harvests, and to avoid sickness).
75
Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1007; see Hagberg, supra note 60, at 99 (arguing earth priests
and elders regard the earth “as a divinity and fear that the violation of rituals may endanger not merely the individual’s
well-being but community life in general”).
76
See Amadou, supra note 61, at 3 (describing a village chief in southern Niger who descended directly from village
founders and who therefore had the ability to “remain in permanent contact with the invisible world,” appease the
spirits and protect the village).
77
Kelley, supra note 9, at 1007.
78
Kelley, supra note 8, at 647.
79
I witnessed a spirit possession ceremony in a rural Zarma village in 1987. A powerful storm had blown through the
village destroying crops and several grass huts in which villagers lived. An interlocutor explained that participants
wanted to know why the damage had been unleashed. When I asked whom they were communicating with, they
answered “irikoy,” which translates to “our keeper.” It is the term that most Zarma people use when they referring to
God in the Islamic tradition.
80
See Amadou, supra note 61, at 4 (describing a zima as a priest healer and an ally of the spirits).
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
68
to land.
81
Typically, only direct descendants of a village’s founders could vie for the position of
village chief.
82
Once selected, he had little prescriptive power and instead acted as first among
equals, convening village leaders and lineage heads to form consensus.
83
Niger’s history is
replete with efforts by the state – at first the colonial regime, later post-independence
governments – to manipulate, coopt, or diminish the chiefs and their authority.
84
The position of
village chief, has, however, endured and today is an intriguing amalgam. Chiefs are rooted in
tradition and considered, at least in many communities, legitimate sources of authority.
85
At the
same time, they act as low-level administrators for the state.
86
They collect taxes, conciliate local
disputes, and, crucially, endorse land transactions.
87
Higher-level regional chiefs, generally referred to as canton chiefs (chefs de canton),
88
also exercised influence over land, but they enjoyed less historical legitimacy.
89
Cantons were
geographic regional divisions imported to Niger by the French colonizers.
90
To aid their
administration of the vast territory (one they had little interest in except its value in blocking
Great Britain’s colonial expansion),
91
the French invented chieftaincies to rule over the cantons
81
See Kelley, supra note 9, at 1019; see also Meyers, infra notes 171-72 and accompanying text (arguing rural
people in Niger still prefer to deal with chiefs on matters involving land).
82
See Kelley, supra note 8, at 653; Amadou, supra note 61, at 3 (arguing the chief of a village in southern Niger
represents legitimate authority, that he presides over political and land-related decisions, and that the position of chief
is elected from among descendants of the family of the first occupants).
83
See Kelley, supra note 8, at 653.
84
See Bron-Saidatou, supra note 26, at 11 (arguing the colonial and post-independence governments passed various
laws intended to diminish chiefs’ authority); see also Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 658, n. 106.
85
See Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 655 (arguing the position of village chief predated the arrival of
the French and so its legitimacy survived colonialists’ machinations); Abdourahaman Chaibou, Les Judge, Le Cadis,
le Chef et les Autres . . . REVUE JURIDIQUE DE SAMAN 5 (1998) (arguing chiefs in Niger act as both legitimate
traditional leaders and as low-level agents of the modern state).
86
See Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 655 (arguing the position of village chief predated the arrival of
the French and so its legitimacy survived colonialists’ machinations); Chaibou, supra note 85, at 5.
87
See infra notes 297-301 and accompanying text.
88
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 654.
89
Id.
90
Id.
91
See Meyer, supra note 20, at 97 (arguing the French occupied Niger to prevent the British from expanding
northward from Sokoto (in present-day Nigeria) and to facilitate France’s plans to sweep across the continent from
Dakar to Djibouti); Korling, supra note 20, at 43 (arguing the French’s interest in Niger was political and strategic,
not economic); Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 651-52.
69
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
they had just created.
92
In some instances, the canton boundaries were in approximate accord with
the domains of pre-colonial regional chiefs, and the new chefs de canton retained at least some
legitimacy in the eyes of rural people.
93
But the French filled many of the chef de canton
positions with their own toadies, including some who were said to come from Niger’s slave class
and therefore lacked legitimate claim to positions of customary leadership.
94
Rural Nigeriens strongly prefer to resolve their disputes at the family or lineage levels.
95
To involve a chief in a dispute or, worse yet a state institution, is to admit that family patriarchs
have failed in their duties.
96
However, where disputes cannot be resolved by lineage heads,
villagers call upon chiefs to conciliate.
97
In deciding among competing access claims, chiefs
apply no fixed rules and followed no established procedures.
98
Instead, they gather historical
evidence from villagers with the longest memories.
99
Whose ancestor cleared the parcel of land
at issue? Did the ancestor give the parcel to another individual, or was it only a loan? Who
planted the fruit trees on edge of the parcel or dug the well, since both these actions are strong
evidence of access rights?
100
Having brought that history to light, the chief would steer the
disputants toward a resolution.
101
Crucially, the resolution often would take account of the
92
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 654.
93
Id. at 655.
94
See Meyer, supra note 20, at 103 (arguing the first Canton Chief in Niamey was viewed as a French collaborator).
95
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 668.
96
Id.
97
Based on many of performing ethnographic research in rural parts of Niger, I can report generally that land disputes
arise for various reasons. Villagers might disagree over which founder laid claim to a particular tract of land, or indeed,
whether a particular ancestor was or was not among the village founders. They might disagree about boundaries
between fields, which typically were (and are) marked by narrow uncultivated strips of land and immovable objects
such as trees. Often, especially in more recent times, village disputes involve disagreement over whether founder’s
lineage gave a field to a late-comer and his descendants (in some instances slaves), or merely loaned it.
98
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 670-71.
99
See, e.g., Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 685-86.
100
Interview with Canton Chief of Koure, Niamey, Republic of Niger (May 3, 2018).
101
I participated in such a dispute resolution gathering in 1986 in the Nigerien village of Fandou Berri. At the time, I
was a Peace Corps volunteer living in the village, and to demonstrate my bona fides, I cultivated my own half-
hectare of millet, the staple crop. Not long before the harvest, a herder’s son fell asleep (at least that was his story)
and his flock wandered into my field and ate much of my crop. In a country where most people’s livelihoods are
based on subsistence agriculture, this was a gravely serious matter. The village chief and a respected marabout
brought the shepherd’s father and uncles to my hut and, after much discussion, agreed that the family would
apologize and, after the harvest, give me a quantity of their grain. I agreed that the resolution as fair, but declined to
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
70
interests of the disputing parties, but also of their ancestors (who now live in the spirit realm),
the black spirits, and the unborn members of the community.
102
Chiefs also protected the prerogatives of secondary rights holders in rural land. Although
men inherited access to agricultural land, their rights were not the equivalent of ownership.
103
Other members of the community might have durable, enforceable rights to other uses of the
same land.
104
For example, women, who are not necessarily from the man’s family unit, might
have the right to gather straw to weave into mats as a source of pocket money.
105
They might
also have the right to pick sauce ingredients or plant a small garden.
106
Traditional healers
might have the right to harvest medicinal herbs.
107
Anyone in the community might have the
right to collect fodder after the harvest to feed farm animals.
108
Younger men and slaves
associated with the village might also have secondary, contingent rights in the land at issue.
These rights are not necessarily secure use rights that would permit them to exclude others, but
are culturally enforceable rights to plant and harvest crops to serve their specific needs.
109
From the existence of these durable, enforceable secondary rights under customary law, it
accept the grain on grounds I was collecting a stipend from Peace Corps and could afford to feed myself. In the end,
everyone was delighted: harmony was preserved.
102
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 672.
103
Id. at 682 (arguing agricultural land in Niger is subject to “overlapping use claims”).
104
See SHIPTON, supra note 8, at 309 (arguing secondary rights holders in Kenya might claim access to thatched
grass, fuelwood, wild foods, or sources of water and minerals); Lawrence C. Becker, Land Sales and the
Transformation of Social Relations and Landscape in Peri-Urban Mali, 46 GEOFORUM 113,122 (2013) (arguing
secondary rights holders in Mali might have access to pasture, wood collection, and other economic activities);
Admos Chimhowu and Phil Woodhouse, Customary vs Private Property Rights? Dynamics and Trajectories of
Vernacular Land Markets in Sub-Saharan Africa, 6 J. OF AGRARIAN CHANGE 346, 347-48 (2006) (arguing
secondary rights in land act as “‘safety-net’ rights” for the community’s poor); see also CHRISTIAN LUND,
LOCAL POLITICS AND THE DYNAMICS OF PROPERTY IN AFRICA 16 (2008) (referring to the same types of
rights in land as “nested hierarchies of estates”); Aparna Polavarapu, Reconciling Indigenous and Women’s Rights to
Land in Sub- Saharan Africa, GA. J. INT’L. & COMP. L. 93, 114 (2013-2014) (referring to women’s secondary
rights in land as “nested” rights)
105
I base this statement on my own observation of women in the Nigerien village of Fandou Berri; see also Polavarapu,
supra note 104, at 111 (describing women’s secondary land rights under customary law in Botswana).
106
Kelley, supra note 8, at 682.
107
Id.
108
Id.
109
Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1007, 1015.
71
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
follows that the holders of primary rights – older male farmers – do not have the right to alienate
their land.
110
Indeed, how could an elder male presume the right to sell land to an outsider when
rights in the land also extend to secondary rights holders, spirits from the past, and the yet-
unborn?
If customary law, which includes land law, functioned properly, the village would enjoy
barka, a term and a concept that does not translate easily into English but includes a spiritual
element which connotes general wellbeing and good luck.
111
Barka arises when members of the
village are living in harmony and the various actors in the spirit realm are appeased.
112
So long as
barka is maintained, the rains will fall regularly, crops will produce generously, and all will be
well among the living.
113
To summarize this archetypal description of customary land law, access rights were based
primarily on proving descent from village founders. All male descendants expected ongoing,
predictable access to agricultural land. Decisions about which land an individual could cultivate
were made by elder males. These elder males included heads of family, lineage heads, and chiefs.
Their decisions about access are influenced by the needs of the spirits and of secondary rights
holders including women, later born men, and slaves. The man who farmed the plot of land could
not be said to own it, because he did not have the right to exclude all others from it. Nor did he
have the right to sell it. He could, however, count on primary access to that land during his
lifetime, and could presume that his sons would inherit undivided shares of the same land. Village
110
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 683; see Hagberg, supra note 60, at 104 (arguing those who attempt to
sell lineage lands in rural Burkina Faso risk sanction from the spirit world).
111
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 647.
112
Id.
113
To some skeptics, the notion of barka may sound suspiciously close to “harmony.” Some commentators have
critiqued the “harmony” thesis of African village dispute resolution as unrealistic, even naïve. See infra note 345.
However, based on my own fieldwork in rural Nigerien villages, I am confident that harmony and good relations
between and among families is what they say they are trying to accomplish. Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note
8, at 694.
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
72
leaders who allowed this system of interlocking, overlapping, nested rights to deteriorate, risked
the wrath of the spirits and the loss of barka.
B.
Complicating the Picture of Customary Law
If the customary Nigerien land law described in the previous section is an ideal, the
contemporary reality can be far more complicated, partly because outside influences have altered
rural life and land. Although many rural Nigerien communities still rely on lineage heads and
traditional chiefs to determine land rights, the second-half of the 20
th
century ushered in a
profusion of new actors and institutions eager for a role in establishing the rules of the game and
determining winners and losers.
1.
The Influence of Colonialism
From the European colonial perspective, Niger was a mostly barren hinterland, so the
French did not arrive on the scene until the dawn of the 20
th
century.
114
France’s approach to
colonialism, sometimes referred to as “direct rule,”
115
assumed that their colonial subjects were
uncivilized but that they could aspire – with sufficient tutelage – to evolve into civilized
Frenchmen.
116
One aspect of civilized life was private ownership and titling of land, which the
French set about establishing in Niger.
117
By the close of the colonial period in 1960, however,
they had made little progress.
118
The fact was that although France claimed to practice direct rule, Niger was mostly an
afterthought and so they limited their investment by settling for what the eminent anthropologist,
114
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 651 (arguing France occupied Niger late in the colonial period,
mainly to prevent Great Brittan’s colonial expansion in West Africa).
115
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 652.
116
Id; See Paul D. Ocheje, “In the Public Interest”: Forced Evictions, Land Rights and Human Development in Africa,
51 J. AFR. L. 173, 185 (2007) (referring to France’s “civilizing mission” when it came to urban planning).
117
See Ambe J. Njoh, Urban Planning as a Tool of Power and Social Control in Colonial Africa, 24 PLAN. PERSP.
301, 306 (2009) (arguing it was French colonial practice to decree that the Civil Code would apply in land matters and
that their motivation was to “legitimize their land entitlements” and commodify land)
118
Njoh, supra note 117, at 309; Hagberg, supra note 60, at 101.
73
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
Sara Berry, has drolly referred to as “hegemony on the cheap.”
119
When it came to land, that
meant introducing the Code Napoléon, including individual ownership and registration of land,
but doing little to enforce it beyond Niamey.
120
It also involved declaring that all “unoccupied”
land, which the French meant all land not subject to individual ownership, belonged to the
state.
121
Once again, however, the vast majority of the population simply ignored that rule and
went on with their lives as before.
122
By the time of Niger’s independence in 1960, the land-related aspects of France’s
civilizing mission had affected rural people in three limited respects. First, it had introduced
the concept, if not the reality, of individual ownership and titling of land.
123
Rural people
became vaguely aware that individual ownership of land was a possibility,
124
even they viewed
that possibility with disinterest or revulsion.
125
Second, the French, who felt the need to
provide housing for colonial officials as well as Nigerien functionaries that worked for the
government, had begun seizing peri-urban farmland and subdividing it into house plots.
126
At
the time, that activity affected relatively few rural Nigeriens, but it set the stage for the rampant
rural land loss which is happening today.
127
Third, they created the quasi-traditional position of
canton chief, which added powerful new actors to the governance of rural land.
128
Otherwise,
the French impact on land law and land use was minimal.
129
119
SARA BERRY, NO CONDITION IS PERMANENT: THE SOCIAL DYNAMICS OF AGRARIAN CHANGE IN
SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA 23-24 (1993); Kelley, supra note 8, at 651.
120
Njoh, supra note 117, at 306.
121
Id.
122
Id.
123
Meyer, supra note 20, at 100.
124
See Kelley, supra note 8, at 682-83, n. 177 (recounting a village elder’s recollection that views about ownership of
land began to evolve starting in 1960s).
125
See id. at 681-82 (quoting a rural farmer saying “nobles do not divide their lands”).
126
See infra notes 208, 210 and accompanying text.
127
See infra text accompanying notes 261-268.
128
See supra text accompanying notes 92-94.
129
Njoh, supra note 117, at 306.
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
74
2.
The Influence of Islam
The rise of Islam in Niger, particularly the recent surge of fundamentalist Islamic
practice, has had more impact on customary land law than the French ever achieved. Trans-
Saharan traders introduced Islam to West Africa in the 8th century.
130
In the mid-14th century,
Mansa Mousa, the ruler of the West African Mali Empire, made the Islamic pilgrimage to Mecca
and wowed the world with his vast wealth.
131
But Islam spread slowly through West Africa,
mainly along trade routes.
132
Niger – a territory always off the beaten track – was late to adopt
the religion in its more orthodox forms.
133
Well into the 20
th
century, most rural Nigeriens professed Islam and adhered strictly to its
Five Pillars
134
but blended Islam with pre-Islamic spirit beliefs. Throughout my many visits to
rural Niger over the past thirty years, pious Islamic friends have adjured me not to whistle, never
to say nice things about a baby’s appearance, never to enter the bush before sunrise, and not to
build a hut on the foundation of recently deceased ancestor’s home, all to avoid agitating the
spirit realm.
135
Although it is true that until recently Islam has been a “stain not always deep”
136
in
Niger, that situation is changing. In recent decades, Niger’s supple blend of Islam and spirit
worship has come under pressure from conservative Islamic influences emanating from the
130
See Kelley, supra note 8, at 648.
131
Al-Umari, Chapter Ten: The Kingdom of Mali and What Appertains to It, in CORPUS OF EARLY AFRICAN
SOURCES FOR WEST AFRICAN HISTORY 252, 269-72 (N. Levtzion & J.F.P Hopkins, eds. 200
132
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 648.
133
See id.
134
Thomas Kelley, Exporting Western Law to the Developing World, 39 GEO. WASH. INT. L. REV. 321, 339 (2007)
(arguing most Nigeriens practice the Five Pillars of Islam, which are 1) the declaration of faith that there is only one
God (Allah) and that Muhammad is God’s messenger; 2) the performance of five daily prayers; 3) the giving of alms to
the poor and needy; 4) fasting during the month of Ramadan; 5) making the pilgrimage to Mecca, if one is able).
135
See Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 650, n. 70. In an interesting sign of Niger’s syncretic religious
practices, when villagers feel the need to protect themselves from vengeful spirits, or to provoke the spirits into
harming their rivals, they consult an Islamic marabous for charms and incantations rather than visiting a zima, who was
the traditional interlocutor to that realm. Amadou, supra note 61, at 158; see supra note 80 and accompanying text
(explaining the powers of zimas).
136
JEAN ROUCH, LES SONGHAY , 59 (Paris: Presses universitaires de France 1954) (1954) (“[e]n fait, l’Islam n’est
q’une teinture plus ou moins profounde”).
75
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
Arabian Peninsula.
137
Young men in particular are increasingly attracted to what Nigeriens refer
to as “reformist” Islam, partly because it is presented by its promoters as a truer, purer, unsullied
version of their religion and, at least according to some commentators, because it condemns
Nigerien customs surrounding bride price payments, which place insuperable financial burdens
on young men and sometimes prevent them from marrying.
138
This gradual but persistent rise of orthodox Islamic beliefs in Niger has led to three
relatively recent changes in customary land law. First, and most simply, it has introduced Islamic
religious leaders as an additional cadre of non-state actors willing to help settle land disputes.
139
By the 1980s, village patriarchs’ and village chiefs’ efforts to mediate land questions in rural
communities routinely involved local Islamic marabouts as part of the process.
140
In some
intractable land disputes, it is now common for one or both parties to seek a ruling by a
regionally prominent Islamic sheik
141
or to a national Islamic association.
142
Second, land-related nostrums in the Koran have led rural residents to a gradual
acknowledgement, if not yet acceptance, of individual ownership and inheritance of land.
143
The
137
See Hagberg, supra note 60, at 115 (arguing orthodox Islam disapproves of land priests, particularly any ritual
addressed to land spirits). Ibrahim, supra note 25, at 9 (arguing Niger is undergoing an “emerging Islamic revival” that
includes the growth of Islamic ascetic practices in daily life”). I have witnessed significant changes in Islamic practice
during my 30 years of visiting rural Nigerien villages. To take only a few examples, village Islamic leaders no longer
permit post-harvest tom-tom dances or traditional games of chance. Village women cover their heads or wear veils
much more frequently than in the 1980s and 90s. Finally, villagers feel constrained when mentioning or invoking the
spirits, though they still come into conversation regularly.
138
See Interview with Young Man Working in Auto Parts Store, Niamey, Republic of Niger (March 4, 2009) (arguing
“Izala” Muslims are popular among young men in Niamey because they condemn bride wealth payment).
139
See Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 668 (describing a land-related dispute in a rural village where the
local marabout helped mediate).
140
Id.
141
See Kelley, Exporting Western Law, supra note 134, at 324-327 (describing an incident where disputing parties
brought the matter to a prominent Islamic figure).
142
See generally, Meyer, supra note 20, at 48 (arguing various Islamic actors, including the Islamic Association of
Niger, sometimes “act in place of the state” in resolving land disputes). See Interview with Village Chief and Group of
Elders, Saabu Dey, Republic of Niger (December 18, 2003) (recounting an instance wher parties to a land dispute
swore oaths before officials of the Associatin Islamique du Niger); Interview with President of the Islamic Association,
Cadis, and Chef de Canton’s Secretary, Say, Republic of Niger (February 25, 2004) (describing the procedure when
disputants swear before the religious leaders from the Association Islamique du Niger).
143
See Ali Abd Al-Kader, Land Property and Land Tenure in Islam, 5 ISLAMIC Quarterly 4, 5 (1959) (noting that
both the Koran and the actions of the early Muslim state show “an express emphasis and encouragement of land
ownership”).
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
76
Koran calls for male descendants to share equally in land and female descendants to receive half-
shares.
144
Thus far, no one I have encountered in rural Niger has suggested abandoning the
customary law that permits only men to inherit land; however, Islamic law, perhaps in
combination with the French colonial legacy, has nudged rural people closer to the view that
land is something to be owned and inherited individually without the mediating influence of
traditional leaders.
145
Finally, the spirits, including the original gangi bi land spirits and the spirits of ancestors,
today play a diminishing role in determining land use and outcomes. It is not that rural people
believe there are no spirits; rather they believe that Islam is ascendant and that the spirits
therefore have less power than they once did.
146
3.
The Influence of Economic Liberalization
Notions about individual ownership of land, registration of land rights, and the
possibility of land sales, were pushed upon rural Nigeriens with much more force starting the
late 1980s and 1990s with the rise of global liberalization.
147
In Niger’s case, the liberal agenda included, among other features, the passage of a
comprehensive land reform law known as the Rural Code and overall government
decentralization, both of which have affected land rights and laid the groundwork for the
transformation of peri-urban land from communal custom to individual ownership.
148
The story of liberalization in Africa is long, complicated, and in some respects tragic,
149
but a summary version must suffice here. When the Berlin Wall fell in 1989 and the Soviet
144
See Mirath, ENCYCLOPEDIA OF ISLAM (P. Bearman et al. eds., 2d ed. 2005).
145
See Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 683 (arguing rural farmers’ understanding of the land the cultivate
is “unsettled” and combines communal tenure with French and Islamic notions of ownership and inheritance).
146
See id. at 649 (arguing rural Nigerien people feel free to blend Islam with spirit worship so long as the Muslim God
is supreme); Interview with Former Resident of Goudel (April 30, 2018), supra note 38 (arguing the spirits do not like
modernity and are losing power).
147
Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1019-20.
148
Kelley, supra note 9, at 1019-20.
149
Id. at 1021 and n. 131; infra notes 164-173 and accompanying text; Kelley, supra note 9 at 1029.
77
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
Union collapsed, the United States became, at least temporarily, the world’s only superpower.
150
If poor countries in the Global South wanted help paying their bills, they could no longer count
on playing the U.S. and the Soviet Union off of one another.
151
They would have to agree to
economic and political reforms dictated by the U.S., its allies, and the international financial
institutions they controlled.
152
Those policies collectively became known as the Washington
Consensus.
153
The Consensus was geared toward shrinking and democratizing the state and allowing
the free hand of the market to work its magic.
154
Governments across Africa, if they wished to
benefit from the Global North’s economic largess, were compelled to slash civil service rolls,
eliminate regulations, privatize state-owned industries, roll back subsidies, and commit to free
and fair elections and democratic governance.
155
Another key tenet of the Washington
Consensus was the need to privatize, title and register land.
156
Based on the writings of the
Peruvian economist Hernando de Soto, the assumption was that poor countries such as Niger
remain poor because its citizens lack secure rights in their own land.
157
The Nigerien farmer
with no formal deed to the land he tills cannot pledge it as collateral to buy fertilizer or a tractor
and thereby intensify his investment.
158
As a result, he sits on an under-exploited pile of “dead
150
See generally, Kelley, supra note 9, at 1029 (arguing the introduction of Western land laws and anti-slavery laws to
Niger was causing Niger’s customary slaves to lost access to agricultural land).
151
See Thomas Kelley, Beyond the Washington Consensus and New Institutionalism: What is the Future of Law and
Development?, N.C. J. OF INT. L. AND COMM. REG. 539, 542 (arguing after the fall of the Berlin Wall Western
nations interpreted their Cold War victory as proof of the value of unregulated free markets).
152
See Kelley, supra note 9, at 1001 (arguing after the fall of the Berlin wall, African countries could no longer play
“the Western and Eastern blocs off of one another").
153
Kelley, supra note 150, at 542; Kelley, Exporting Western Law, supra note 134, at 328.
154
Kelley, supra note 150, at 542.
155
See Kelley, supra note 134, at 327-28.
156
Kelley, supra note 9, at 1002.
157
Id.; see Tor A. Benjaminsen et al., Formalization of Land Rights: Some Empirical Evidence from Mali, Niger and
South Africa, 26 LAND USE POL’Y 28, 29 (2008) (arguing De Soto’s book The Mystery of Capital gave direction to
an entire new movement in law and development); see generally, HERNANDO DE SOTO, THE MYSTERY OF
CAPITAL, WHY CAPITALISM TRIUMPHS IN THE WEST AND FAILS EVERYWHERE ELSE (2000).
158
Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1002.
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
78
capital” and remains mired in poverty.
159
The key to unlocking prosperity in poor countries,
therefore, was the reform and formalization of land rights,
160
which would allow property
owners to “revive their ‘dead’ capital and generate surplus value from their assets.”
161
To summarize in one sentence the results of the Consensus economic policies –
including land titling – they inflicted significant pain and suffering on poor people in the Global
South while producing few of the advertised economic benefits.
162
Nevertheless,
Niger was an early and enthusiastic adopter Consensus policies, including land titling.
163
In 1993, in keeping with the Consensus and just as the country was embarking on its first
experiment with democratically elected government, it adopted a comprehensive new set of land
laws, referred to as the Rural Code,
164
aimed at bringing order and consistency to what aid experts
and central government officials viewed as the country’s confusing jumble of land customs and
practices.
165
It was an enormously ambitious scheme that can only be summarized here. It
envisaged the creation of a series of land commissions at various levels of government and
procedures by which those who control land could obtain and register individual title to it.
166
In
theory, the Rural Code and its administrative processes took a culturally sensitive approach to land
reform in that it claimed that communal rights and secondary rights – the sort of customary land
rights described in Part III.A., above – were eligible for registration and protection.
167
However, as
the Rural Code began to roll out, it became abundantly clear that government agents were intent on
159
DE SOTO, supra note 157, at 163.
160
See generally Benjaminsen et al., supra note 157, at 29.
161
Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1002.
162
See Kelley, Exporting Western Law, supra note 134, at 328-29 (arguing the track record of Washington
consensus reforms “has been poor”); Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1002-3 (arguing studies
of privatization find that “few of the predicted economic benefits actually materialized”).
163
See Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1021 (arguing Niger launched a “full scale land reform
effort” that aimed to “convert Niger from customary land tenure to a Western system of freehold ownership and
titling”).
164
Code rural [C. Rural.] [Rural Code] art. 93-115 (Fr.).
165
Kelley, supra note 9, at 1022.
166
See Meyer, supra note 20, at 249-50.
167
See Kelley, supra note 9, at 1021.
79
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
registering land in the names of individuals, not groups, as part of an overall effort to comply with
Consensus dictates and “modernize” Niger’s land laws.
168
Several excellent articles and books have been written about Niger’s attempts at land law
reform.
169
The short version is that in more than two decades, the reforms have had limited
effect.
170
Peasant farmers find the process of land registration cumbersome and expensive, and
they still generally prefer to deal directly with traditional chiefs.
171
The chiefs, who receive
prestige and money by recognizing land claims and conciliating land disputes, encourage the view
that nothing has changed, that other local political actors such as mayors and councilors are
impotent, and that the Rural Code’s land commissions are a waste of time.
172
Even where farmers
are motivated to formally register their lands – and some are, particularly where there are disputes
over access or the threat of state expropriation – the government often lacks resources and
personnel to maintain the necessary registers.
173
168
Id.; Chimhowu & Woodhouse, supra note 104, at 347 (arguing land registration schemes in Africa claim to register
group rights but usually aim for individualized ownership “formalized in a written title to physically-demarcated
land”); see also Lorenzo Cotula et. al., Land Tenure and Administration in Africa: Lessons of Experience and
Emerging Issues 13 (2004) (arguing Niger’s Rural Code purports to respect customary rights but places the new land
system firmly under the control of non-customary actors); UBINK, supra note 57, at 222 (arguing titling schemes in the
African context often ignore secondary rights holders).
169
See e.g., CHRISTIAN LUND, LAW, POWER, AND POLITICS IN NIGER: LAND STRUGGLES AND THE RURAL CODE IN
NIGER (1998).
170
Bron-Saidatou, supra note 26, at 25 (arguing less than 3% of parcels of eligible land have been registered in
Niger).
171
Cotula et al., supra note 168, at 12; Andrew R. Falk, Ahead of the Curve: Promoting Land Tenure Security in Sub-
Saharan Africa To Protect the Environment, SEATTLE J. FOR SOC. JUST. 1, 35 (2016) (arguing titling schemes in sub-
Saharan Africa are often “arduous and expensive”); see Meyer, supra note 20, at 251.
172
MEYER, supra note 20, at 252 (arguing canton chiefs use their customary authority to block or authorize land
transactions even though they have not formal authority under the Rural Code).
173
See Cotula et al., supra note 168, at 5 (arguing implementation of Niger’s Rural Code has been slow due to lack of
resources).
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
80
4.
The Influence of Government Decentralization
As Niger’s government began implementing the Rural Code the early 1990s, it
simultaneously dove into government decentralization, which is another aspect of the standard
consensus liberalization package.
174
Lawmakers hoped these two reforms would mesh
seamlessly and that the new procedures for registering rural land would be carried out by
grassroots officials, including locally elected councilors and mayors whose positions were
created by the new decentralization legislation.
175
That was not how things turned out.
176
The theory behind decentralization was that if responsibility for revenue collection and
service delivery were pushed down from the central government to locally elected officials,
there would be greater accountability and efficiency.
177
Decisions on whether to invest in
road maintenance or the construction of markets would be made at the local level and local
people would hold their officials – local councilors and mayors whose offices had been
created by the decentralization legislation
– accountable for results.
178
If local leaders spent
public money unwisely or irresponsibly, or more to the point, if tax revenues disappeared as a
result of corruption, local voters would know it and would elect new local representatives.
179
Likewise, decisions about land ownership and registration, whether in rural or urban areas,
would be most accurately and efficiently carried out by local governments and local
174
MEYER, supra note 20, at 110 (describing decentralization as one of the “watchwords” of democratization in
Niger).
175
See Cotula et al., supra note 168, at 12 (arguing countries in sub-Saharan Africa attempted to decentralize
control over land within the broader context of political decentralization).
176
See infra notes 183-186 and accompanying text; NJOH, supra note 27, at 549 (arguing that decentralization in
Niger never really materialized).
177
See KORLING, supra note 20, at 105 (arguing that aid agencies promoted decentralization as bringing
governmental administration closer to the people and increased accountability, transparency, and efficiency, but that
it just made local level governance more complex).
178
Id. at 113 (a goal of decentralization was that citizens would see where their money was going, thereby
legitimizing taxation).
179
See id. at 106 (arguing decentralization in Niger was supposed to create accountability, transparency, and
efficiency). Interview with Former Mayor of Niamey Commune 5, Niamey, Republic of Niger (May 2, 2018)
(arguing “it’s harder to see corruption when it’s farther away?).
81
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
officials.
180
After all, they would be closest to the facts on the ground and they would be
accountable to local land users.
181
More than twenty years in, most observers judge decentralization to be a failure both in
rural areas and in Niamey.
182
One problem was that, the scheme gave local governments major
responsibility for service delivery – including responsibility for implementing the Rural Code’s
new land registration procedures – but virtually no resources with which to achieve those
tasks.
183
Also, central government actors who had long enjoyed unquestioned authority were
reluctant to surrender their prerogatives, including the rent seeking opportunities that go along
with controlling finances, so they simply delayed and obfuscated when it came to devolving
power to lower levels of government.
184
In the end, all that decentralization accomplished was to add a low-level,
comparatively powerless set of government actors to an already crowded and chaotic
institutional matrix.
185
Before decentralization, a jumble of customary chiefs, Islamic
religious leaders, and representatives of the central government vied with one another for
legitimacy and power in both rural and urban areas.
186
Decentralization laws added local
councilors and mayors to the mix, a group that brought no historical legitimacy and no
180
See Interview with Former Mayor of Niamey Commune 5, Niamey, Republic of Niger (May 2, 2018). Former
Mayor of Niamey Commune 5, supra note 180 (arguing land conversions were better managed by local commune
governments, as opposed to the CUN government, because they were more accountable to local residents).
181
Interview with Former Mayor of Niamey Commune 5 (May 2, 2018).
182
Korling, supra note 20, at 106-107 (arguing that in many areas decentralization simply made things more
complicated by adding to the already confused jumble of political actors involved in land and the delivery of
government services).
183
Id. at 107-108; Cotula et al., supra note 168, at 5. Njoh, supra note 27, at 540.
184
Korling, supra note 20, at 110 (arguing the subdivision of land was a “valuable resource” and “source of illicit
enrichment” for governmental actors, and that the central government officials won the struggle against local
governments).
185
Id. at 106; see Meyer, supra note 20, at 24-27, 30-34 (arguing numerous Nigerien institutions vie with one
another for authority over land transactions).
186
See Meyer, supra note 20, at 24-27; 30-34.
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
82
additional resources with which to entice adherents.
187
They ended up being easily out-
competed by central government authorities, who never removed their fingers from the purse
strings, and by traditional chiefs, who either isolated them by convincing rural people to
ignore them, or coopted them by having their own relatives run for local office.
188
The failure of decentralization has contributed to an atmosphere of “general
dysfunction”
189
when it comes to land registration in rural areas.
190
Because there are no
resources to create and maintain cadastral systems at the lower levels of government, and
because there is constant competition from other actors, precious few parcels of rural land
are actually being registered in rural areas.
191
In spite of these institutional failures, the Rural Code (including its plans for titling
and registration of land) and government decentralization have in combination affected
land and land use in peri-urban areas in two respects. First, they have helped spread the
word about the concept of individual ownership and registration of land. Although land
ownership is not an entirely new concept, having been introduced to rural communities by
the French and by the rise of “reformist” Islam, until recently it has been more of a rumor
than a reality.
192
187
Id. at 224, 251 (arguing the institutions of the state lack legitimacy in land matters, that people still turn to chiefs
instead of local officials); Bron-Saidatou, supra note 26, at 20 (arguing commune level governments in peri-urban
areas lack the power the money to control land matters).
188
Korling, supra note 20, at 106, 119-120.
189
Bron-Saidatou, supra note 26, at 21
190
Id. at 24.
191
Id. at 24 (estimating that 3% of rural land in Niger has been registered under the Rural Code).
192
See, Kelley, supra note 9.
83
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
IV.
The Death of Customary Law in Peri-Urban Niamey
Peri-urban development around African cities tends to follow major paved roads that lead
to the countryside, and eventually link to other major cities and towns.
193
Since 1986, for more
than 30 years, I have regularly traveled on Niamey’s Filingue Road, which heads east-northeast
out of the capital toward the town of Filingue.
194
Therefore, I have had a consistent reference
point by which to track Niamey’s growth. As late as the mid-2000s, the Filingue Road had one
gas station across from the Wadata Market, in what was the edge of the city. Drivers, including
me, often filled up there before leaving town and venturing into the bush. There was sporadic
development along the road beyond the gas station, but few permanent structures. As one exited
the city, the landscape quickly turned to millet fields and tree nurseries. The first village, Saga
Gourou, approximately 10 kilometers from the Wadata gas station, looked and felt as if it
belonged to a different world, a rural world.
When I drove out of Niamey along the Filingue Road in 2018, I counted eleven gas
stations beyond my old fill-up spot.
195
The road was lined with commercial buildings,
compounds, and, behind that commercial strip, residential neighborhoods as far as the eye could
193
See Janine M Ubink, Courts and Peri-Urban Practice Customary Land Law in Ghana, U. GHANA L. J. 25
(2002-2004) (arguing development of peri-urban areas in Ghana follows main roads because that is where
electricity is most commonly available).
194
I base my description of the Filingue Road, officially named RN 25, on decades of observation. I served as a
Peace Corps volunteer in Niger from 1986 to 1988 and was posted in a village approximately 50 kilometers east-
northeast of Niamey in the general direction of the town of Filingue. I regularly rode a motorcycle to and from
Niamey along that route. In late 1990s, when I began performing ethnographic legal research in the same zone, I
regularly traveled the Filingue Road in public transportation. Still later, when I had a Fulbright Scholarship in
Niger from 2003-2004, I drove a private vehicle out the Filingue Road several times each week to perform
fieldwork. I have continued to visit that zone regularly, most recently in May, 2018.
195
See Interview with Hamdallaye Canton Chief, supra note 17 (describing development along the Filingue
Road between Niamey and Hamdallaye).
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
84
see. The rampant development has engulfed the village of Saga Gourou. Clearly, something
dramatic is happening to land around Niamey.
196
A.
History of Land in Niamey and Environs
The city of Niamey was, to a large extent, a colonial creation.
197
Before the French
arrived at the turn of the 20
th
century, there were several villages along the banks of the Niger
River, in the area of present-day Niamey, but no significant cities or towns.
198
During the
early years of their colonial project in Niger, the French vacillated between Zinder and
Niamey as their center of activity.
199
But Niamey had attractive views of the Niger River and
an airy plateau where the colonial overlords could build their offices and residences. In 1926,
the French established a permanent capital there.
200
The airy plateau favored by the French was located between two villages that became
important actors in the story of Niamey’s peri-urban land transformation. To the west, and
somewhat upriver, was the village of Goudel.
201
To the east, and somewhat downriver, was
the village of Gamkallay.
202
Historically, their fields were divided by a watercourse and gully
that now bisects Niamey.
203
Today, both former villages are considered neighborhoods of the
capital city.
204
196
NB: Much of this description, including the presence of the eleven gas stations beyond Wadata, can be verified
on Google Maps. The first village, Saga Gorou, is not identified by name but you can see the settlement on the
satellite version.
197
Meyer, supra note 20, at 93.
198
See id. (arguing in pre-colonial days, present-day Niamey was away from major trade routes and a “zone of
refuge” for diverse peoples).
199
NJOH, supra note 27, at 546. Meyer, supra note 20, at 99 (arguing the city of Zinder, located in eastern Niger,
was a city of longstanding political and economic importance.
200
MEYER, supra note 20, at 99.
201
Id. at 94.
202
Id.
203
See id.at 96 (arguing Gamkalle and Goudel originally controlled the land that later became Niamey and that
the dividing line between them was the ravine of Gunti Yena, a stream that enters the Niger River).
204
Based on personal knowledge, Gamkalle and Goudel are not the only villages incorporated into Niamey over
the decades. For example, Gaway, a pre-colonial fishing settlement on the banks of the Niger River, was displaced
during the 1970s to make room for the present-day Hotel Gawaye. The government moved Gaway’s residents
85
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
The French set about transforming land law in their new colony, but, as discussed in Part
III, they made little progress in rural areas.
205
The vast majority of Niger’s people simply
ignored the putative changes in land law and went on with their lives as before.
206
But this was less the case in and around Niamey. By the 1950s, the colonial regime was
beginning to carve up rural land on the city’s outskirts – largely in what had been the
agricultural fields of Goudel and Gamkale – to produce subdivided residential parcels, mostly
for civil servants and veterans who had regular salaries.
207
Because the French did not
recognize customary claims, they simply requisitioned what they considered empty land and
dedicated it to their preferred uses.
208
The colonists’ subdivision of land around Niamey for residential purposes was slow and
steady until the late 1950s,
209
when it began to accelerate as a result of economic growth, high
birth rates, and two great droughts in 1972-73 and 1983-84.
210
Rural people were being
pushed by crisis but also pulled by opportunity as pre- and post-Independence governments
focused their limited resources on developing schools, health care facilities, and other
infrastructure in cities.
211
The rapid growth in urban population outstripped the government’s
across the Niger River to a newly settled area called Haro Banda and compensated them by granting them multiple
subdivided house plots. Another village, Saga, had much of its territory expropriated by Niger’s government to
build Diori Hamani Airport on what was then the outskirts of the capital. Today, Niamey has grown around and
beyond the airport and Saga is considered a suburban neighborhood.
205
See supra notes 120-122 and accompanying text.
206
Id.
207
MEYER, supra note 20, at 105; see Korling, supra note 20, at 73 (arguing that since the colonial period urban
planning in Niamey has focused on subdivision of land, but that the planning has always fallen behind actual
expansion).
208
Meyer, supra note 20, at 3.
209
Motcho, supra note 48, at 2 (describing Niamey’s rapid population growth during the late colonial and early
independence periods and rising demand for parcels of land).
210
Meyer, supra note 20, at 109.
211
Ocheje, supra note 116, at 187.
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
86
ability to convert land from farms to house plots,
212
and the result was the appearance of
informal, mostly unplanned neighborhoods around Niamey’s periphery.
213
When the French colonialists departed in 1960 and the post-independence
government took control, little changed, at least in the realm of law.
214
The newly
independent country declared that the French Civil Code would continue to be the law of the
land,
215
and the vast majority of Niger’s citizens continued to ignore that formal law, just as
they had under the French.
216
In Niamey, however, the post-independence government held
more sway than in rural areas and was able, at least to a certain extent, to continue the
colonial land practices and policies.
217
Particularly during the reign of Sayni Kountche, a
military dictator who ruled from 1974-1987, the Nigerien state carried on with expropriating
significant tracts of land on the periphery of the city, all by military decree, and dedicating it
to providing housing for the city’s growing population.
218
As was true during colonialism,
much of the land was taken from farmers from the villages of Gamkale and Goudel.
212
Korling, supra note 20, at 73.
213
Meyer, supra note 20, at 107 (arguing some of the informal neighborhoods were later formalized while others
were not).
214
Njoh, supra note 27, at 547, 549; Meyer, supra note 20, at 107.
215
Njoh, supra note 27, at 550
216
Njoh, supra note 27 (Niger’s post-independence governments periodically issued decrees and passed laws
attempting to reform land practice. For example, in the 1970s, the military regime of President Sayni Kountche
decreed a new policy of mise en valeur: the notion that henceforth all rural land would “belong” to those who were
farming it); Kelley, supra note 8, Squeezing Parakeets Into Pigeon Holes: The Effect of Globalization and State
Legal Reform in Niger on Indigenous Zarma Law, at 685. Many said that in fact this policy was Kountche’s attempt
to remove or at least weaken chiefs’ power of land tenure matters; Kelley, supra note 8, Squeezing Parakeets Into
Pigeon Holes: The Effect of Globalization and State Legal Reform in Niger on Indigenous Zarma Law, at 685. In
the end, it really did not matter, since resilient rural Nigeriens largely ignored that policy too..
217
Meyer, supra note 20, at 107.
218
See supra note 208 (arguing Niger’s post-independence governments seized his family’s lands without
compensation and dedicated them to Niamey’s Green Belt); Kelley, supra note 8, at 138 (arguing the Kountche
regime also continued the expansion of the colonialist’s Green Belt).
87
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
B.
Decentralization Struggles Lead to Chaos in Urban and
Peri-Urban Land Management
Fundamental changes in land law, changes that have profoundly affected the lives and
livelihoods of people living in peri-urban zones, did not accelerate until the 1990s, the era of
economic liberalization, democratization, and government decentralization described in Part
III, above. Niger, whether by choice or compulsion, fully implemented Washington
Consensus reforms including land law reform and government decentralization.
While those
policies had comparatively little impact in isolated rural areas,
219
they began to alter peoples’
lives in peri- urban zones around the capital.
The land transformation in and around Niamey began in earnest as an indirect result of
government decentralization. In 2002, Niamey’s central government, the Urban Community of
Niamey (“CUN”) was divided into five separate local governments, known as communes, each
with significant responsibility for providing municipal services.
220
Importantly, each of the
urban communes had the authority to subdivide and sell land on its periphery.
221
The
communes quickly realized that the central government was going to do little to help pay for
219
Njoh, supra note 27 (Niger’s post-independence governments periodically issued decrees and passed laws
attempting to reform land practice. For example, in the 1970s, the military regime of President Sayni Kountche
decreed a new policy of mise en valeur: the notion that henceforth all rural land would “belong” to those who were
farming it); Kelley, supra note 8, Squeezing Parakeets Into Pigeon Holes: The Effect of Globalization and State
Legal Reform in Niger on Indigenous Zarma Law, at 685. Many said that in fact this policy was Kountche’s attempt
to remove or at least weaken chiefs’ power of land tenure matters; Kelley, supra note 8, Squeezing Parakeets Into
Pigeon Holes: The Effect of Globalization and State Legal Reform in Niger on Indigenous Zarma Law, at 685. In
the end, it really did not matter, since resilient rural Nigeriens largely ignored that policy too.; Meyer, supra note 20,
at 107.
220
Meyer, supra note 20, at 227.
221
Meyer, supra note 20, at 111.
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
88
governmental services,
222
and that converting peri-urban land from farms to house plots was a
source of desperately needed revenue.
223
The communes quickly realized that the central government was going to do little to
help pay for governmental services,
224
and that converting peri-urban land from farms to house
plots was a source of desperately-needed revenue.
225
Not incidentally, subdividing and selling
land also created rent-seeking opportunities for commune officials, of which they took full
advantage.
226
With these dynamics at play, the urban communes enthusiastically dove into the
business of converting farmland around the city into subdivided house plots.
227
During this period, however, there was growing tension between Niamey’s newly
empowered commune governments and the CUN. From the CUN’s perspective, the
communes squabbled with one another, refused to collaborate, and prevented the CUN from
playing its rightful role as coordinator.
228
From the communes’ perspective, the CUN simply
222
Kelley, supra note 8, at 682; LOERENZO COTULA, ET. AL., LAND TENURE AND ADMINISTRATION IN
AFRICA: LESSONS OFEXPERIENCE AND EMERGING ISSUES 13 (2004) (arguing Niger’s Rural Code
purports to respect customary rights but places the new land system firmly under the control of non-customary
actors); Ubink, Tenure Security, supra note 57, at 222 (arguing titling schemes in the African context often ignore
secondary rights holders); Chimhowu & Woodhouse, supra note 104, at 347 (arguing land registration schemes in
Africa claim to register group rights but usually aim for individualized ownership “formalized in a written title to
physically-demarcated land”); Njoh, supra note 27, at 540 (arguing the decentralization that was supposed to
accompany the Rural Code “never really materialized”); Meyer, supra note 20, at 224, 251 (arguing the institutions
of the state lack legitimacy in land matters, that people still turn to chiefs instead of local officials); Bron-Saidatou,
supra note 26, at 20 (arguing commune level governments in peri-urban areas lack the power the money to control
land matters)
223
See Interview with Former Mayor of Commune 5 of Niamey, Niamey, Republic of Niger (May 2, 2018) (arguing
the communes produced revenues from developing peri-urban land and spent it on service provision); Meyer, supra
note 20, at 227; Korling, supra note 20, at 109 (arguing zoning power appeared to the commune governments as a
“golden opportunity” to produce revenue).
224
See Korling, supra note 20, at 108 (arguing commune governments were given much responsibility for service
delivery but few means to raise funds).
225
Meyer, supra note 20, at 227 (arguing that subdividing land provided revenues to commune-level governments).
226
See Korling, supra note 20, at 81 (arguing that the process of subdividing land is complicated and corrupt);
Issaka, supra note 1 (arguing that in the 1990s the communes were practically the only ones subdividing land around
Niamey and that corruption had been at the heart of the system).
227
Meyer, supra note 20, at 233.
228
Id. at 227
89
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
did not want to relinquish its centralized power.
229
By 2011 the struggle between Niamey’s
communes and the CUN was over and, for political reasons beyond the scope of this article,
230
the CUN had reasserted control of city government, including the development of peri-urban
land.
231
The CUN’s inability to handle the volume of land transactions and the entry of private
developers to the market conjunctively catalyzed chaos in peri-urban land development.
232
C.
Enter the Private Developers
Before the CUN mayor’s office could bring order to peri-urban land development, it
was overtaken by the arrival of private land developers in the market.
233
Legal changes in the
late 1990s authorized private development,
234
but its influence was not felt until the mid-
2000s when a governmental decree definitively removed the state’s monopoly and made it
possible for anyone possessing peri-urban land to subdivide and sell it.
235
The idea was to
unburden the government from constantly having to search for resources to carry out
necessary improvements for the process of converting agricultural land to house plots: the
provision of roads, public buildings, water, electricity, and other infrastructure.
236
The effect,
however, was to permit private actors, particularly those with working capital, to suddenly and
entirely take over land development on the edge of the city.
237
There has been a boom in the
229
Interview with Former Mayor of Niamey Commune 5 (May 2, 2018), supra note 180.
230
In brief, Niger experienced a coup d’état in 2010 and the military government preferred to govern the city by
naming its own top officials. See Meyer supra note 20, at 228.
231
Id. at 113, 22
232
Id. at 228 (arguing the CUN mayor’s office attempted to centralize all land-related record-keeping, resulting in
boxes of disorganized records piled high in the corridors, complete lack of file verification, and some parcels being
sold multiple times).
233
Id. at 229.
234
Issaka, supra note 1 (arguing many private developers entered the Niamey land market after legal reforms in
1997); Meyer, supra note 20, at 118.
235
Meyer, supra note 20, at 227, 229 (arguing private developers were not fully able to participate in development
of peri-urban land until a government decree in 2000).
236
Id. at 229.
237
Id. at 235, 238.
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
90
development of peri-urban land since 2010,
238
and every new subdivision around Niamey has
been undertaken by private developers.
239
Most of the leading private actors have been individuals who, through personal
contacts and prior experience, know how to navigate the tortuous bureaucratic process
involved in converting farmland into suburbs.
240
Some acquired their knowledge by
working on the inside of the state bureaucracy and their core expertise is keeping up on the
constant modifications to the arcane procedural requirements.
241
Others have become
powerful private actors because of family ties to chiefs in the peri-urban zones.
242
They use
their connections to identify potential sellers of land and to negotiate with lineage heads.
243
The former group of intermediaries are familiar with the corridors of power and the constant
flux in the rules, while the latter keep tabs on who owns which lands and who might be
convinced to sell.
244
The most effective of the middlemen combine both competencies.
245
They propose their service directly to customary owners, offering the enticing possibility of
selling their land without having to engage directly with the distasteful, even dreaded,
government bureaucracy; and often offering better terms than those offered by commune-
level mayors’ offices (before municipal government was re- centralized) or the CUN (before
it was squeezed out of the game).
246
The entrance of private developers into peri-urban land markets have led to the
238
Id. at 242.
239
Issaka, supra note 1 (arguing private developers have become more powerful actors than government); Meyer,
supra note 20, at 229.
240
See Meyer, supra note 20, at 236.
241
Id.
242
Id.
243
Id.
244
Id.
245
See Meyer, supra note 20, at 239.
246
Id. at 237.
91
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
emergence of symbiotic, mafia-like networks between the private actors and government
officials.
247
The developers, many of whom have grown vastly wealthy, grease the necessary
palms in the state bureaucracy to ensure their development plans are approved,
248
whether or
not those plans comply with state requirements, or the best practices for infrastructure, public
space, and the like.
249
In recent years, the developers’ corrupt influence is rumored to go even
deeper and higher.
250
Some have become so wealthy that they are able to pour vast amounts
of money into electoral campaigns to ensure the election of officials who are sympathetic to
their projects.
251
Once this is accomplished and their friends are in office, the tortuous
governmental regulatory and permitting processes become crystal clear and streamlined for
the politicians’ patron but remains tortuous and opaque for the patron’s competitors.
252
It is
common knowledge in Niamey that these relationships reach the highest levels of
government, which means no bureaucrat, at any level of the state apparatus, can safely
impede the private developers’ plans – whether for corrupt or legitimate public safety
reasons.
253
247
See id. at 241.
248
See Korling, supra note 20, at 80, 91 (arguing the sale of peri-urban house plots is the source of corrupt
practices, that Niamey city hall is a “locus of negotiations and access,” and that government officials are typically
bribed by offering them plots in the subdivisions they authorize); Interview with Former Niamey Mayor of
Commune 5 (insert interview source, and location) (May 2, 2019), supra note 180 (arguing “[t]he only way to
move a [housing] project forward is to engage in corruption” by paying ministry officials).
249
See Korling, supra note 20, at 90; Interview with Former Mayor of Niamey Commune 5 (insert interview
source, and location) (May 2, 2019), supra note 180.
250
See Interview with Former Mayor of Niamey Commune 5 (insert interview source, and location) (May 2, 2018),
supra note 180 (arguing the land system around Niamey is “full of corruption,” that faulty development plans are
routinely approved by corrupt CUN officials, and that the office of Niger’s president overrules decisions by lower
level government offices that might block development plans).
251
Meyer, supra note 20, at 241.
252
Id.
253
See id. at 244-245, 259; see generally Interview with Former Mayor of Niamey Commune 5 (insert interview
source, and location) (May 2, 2019), supra note 180 (arguing his private business was suffering because those in
political power were steering business away from him).
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
92
As in rural areas,
254
in peri-urban zones there is an ongoing struggle over who has
formal authority to authorize the transition from farmland to suburban house plots.
255
Chiefs
in peri- urban zones vie with formal CUN officials, who in turn vie with various central
government ministers and their underlings whose portfolios touch on land development.
256
But since the entrance of wealthy, politically connected private developers onto the scene, the
contest for formal authority matters less
257
because the private actors simply push aside the
competing organs of the state and carry out their development plans in whatever way will
maximize their profits.
258
The state has become one actor among many, and in most instances
it not the most powerful one.
259
The result, discussed in more detail in Part V., below, is that
it has become “impossible to manage the peri-urban land for the good of all, especially for the
lowest level of society.”
260
D. The Current Situation
Today, land in the vicinity of Niamey is coveted and the market is frenzied.
261
Although
the large private developers described above are dominant players and reap the greatest rewards,
it seems that everyone with capital to invest is jostling to get into the game.
262
Business people
254
Meyer, supra note 20, at 225.
255
Meyer supra note 20, at 225.
256
Id. at 211, 225, 256 (arguing the Ministries of Environment, Urbanism, Cadaster, and Education all have
claims to authorize peri-urban land transactions, but that Urbanism is the most powerful so private developer
with clout skip the other ministries and go straight to Urbanism).
257
See Issaka, supra note 1 (arguing the developers and their highly placed patrons in central government succeeded
in pushing the lower level commune governments out of the way even though they were supposed to have authority
over subdividing land); Meyer, supra note 20, at 225.
258
Meyer, supra note 20, at 224; Interview with A Highly Placed Official in Niger’s Ministry of Environment and
of Durable Development, Niamey, Republic of Niger (May 11, 2018) (arguing the rise of private developers means
no one is taking account of the public interest and it is now all about generating profit).
259
Meyer, supra note 20, at 225.
260
Id.
261
See Issaka, supra note 1 (employing the French term “combat foncier” meaning “land combat” to describe
the real estate market in peri-urban areas around Niamey).
262
See Interview with Retired Office Worker, Niamey, Republic of Niger (insert interview source, and location)
(April 28, 2018) (describing his purchases of various empty house lots in towns near Niamey); see also Interview
93
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
who have no background in land development and whose main activities focus on general
commerce or transportation, are buying up empty lots in the fast-spreading peri-urban
neighborhoods with an eye toward flipping them or developing them.
263
Those with sufficient
means purchase the lots in large quantities,
264
often in cahoots with government officials with
whom they split the profits when prices rise.
265
While others purchase large tracts of agricultural
land located far from the city;
266
and some plan to subdivide the land quickly and sell to smaller-
scale speculators.
267
Others intend to sit on the distant land until the fast-expanding city
approaches their holdings and pushes the value upward.
268
Poor urban Nigeriens are nowhere to be seen in this scramble for peri-urban land. The
government, with the support and advice of aid agencies, has begun in recent years entering into
public-private partnerships to establish new logement social (“social” or “affordable” housing) in
with Two Real Estate Developers, Niamey, Republic of Niger (insert interview source, and location) (April 30,
2018) (discussing where one developer was a former lawyer and the other was until recently a “documentary
filmmaker” and still had that profession on his business card).
263
See Interview with El Hadji Merchant, Niamey, Republic of Niger (insert interview source, and location) (May
4, 2018) (describing a merchant with no development experience revealing his plans for developing recently
purchased peri-urban land); Interview with a Businessman, Niamey, Republic of Niger (insert interview source, and
location) (May 4, 2018) (describing an uneducated businessman with no prior experience in land development
revealing his participation in a large peri-urban social housing development); Interview with Two Real Estate
Developers, supra note 262 (describing two principals of a social housing project, one a former lawyer, the other a
documentary film maker).
264
See e.g., Interview with El Hadji Merchant, supra note 263.
265
Meyer, supra note 20, at 225.
266
See Interview with Two Real Estate Developers, supra note 262 (describing a housing development located
approximately 30 kilometers from Niamey); Interview with El Hadji Merchant, supra note 263 (describing his
purchase and conversion of land approximately 20 kilometers outside of Niamey).
267
See Issaka, supra note 1 (arguing many speculators have entered Niamey’s land markets); Cotula et. al., supra
note 168, at 27 (arguing many urban elites are speculating in peri-urban land markets).
268
See Interview with El Hadji Merchant, supra note 263 (arguing he will leave much of his recent peri-urban
land purchase “in reserve” to allow prices to rise).
Major business actors are not the only ones fueling the red-hot peri-urban land markets. Peri-urban land
is one of Niger’s few investment opportunities, so many salaried employees (primarily civil servants) are
purchasing multiple undeveloped plots in recently subdivided neighborhoods outside of town, often while living
in small rented lodgings in the city. Meyer, supra note 20, at 233. In fact, it is rare that the first purchaser of a
newly subdivided plot actually constructs a house and moves in. Id. Most initial buyers are investors and often it
is the second or third purchaser who constructs a residence. Id. at 234 ((offering an example of one house plot in a
peri-urban neighborhood that originally was purchased for 60,000 CFA (approximately $ at current exchange
rates), that changed hands twice, and eventually sold for 2 million CFA to the person who constructed a house.)
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
94
peri-urban zones.
269
However, in spite of the “social” moniker, little, if any, of the resulting
housing is within the means of poor people.
270
From the perspective of an academic studying land in Niger, this is a fascinating
transitional moment in which the rules governing peri-urban land and land use are changing
rapidly. But from the perspective of farmers living in peri-urban zones this transition signals
and end to a way of life. Whether their land is purchased by a developer, or condemned by the
state, once official title has been printed and properly registered, the purchaser’s rights are
secure and the rural people, along with their rural beliefs, rural ways of life, and rural
livelihoods, are out of the game. The transition to suburbs is irreversible
271
and the land
becomes a commodity like oranges on special in Niamey’s Petit Marche.
272
269
Alexandra Biehler, Armelle Choplin, Marie Morelle, Le Logement Sociale en Afriquie: Un Modele a
(Re)inventer?, (May 18, 2015), available at https://www.metropolitiques.eu/Le-logement-social-en-Afrique-
un.html (Last visited Sept. 23, 2019) (at p .1 arguing NGOs and international agencies have supported social
housing). Meyer, supra note 20, at 240 (mentioning social housing in Niger and arguing it does not benefit the
poor).
Based on personal observation, these social housing neighborhoods are popping up like mushrooms in
rural areas around Niamey. Because they are being developed well outside the boundaries of the city, they can be
a startling, incongruous sight as one drives through the bush. The completed neighborhood can include hundreds
of residential units, typically a mix of one, two, and three-bedroom cement, metal-roofed houses, each with a
small, walled concession surrounding it, all packed closely together. See Interview with Two Real Estate
Developers, supra note 262 (describing a social housing site under construction approximately 30 kilometers
from Niamey). They often are completely surrounded by agricultural fields where farmers go about their
traditional routines of planting and cultivating subsistence crops and husbanding their animals. See id. (describing
a new social housing site next to what appeared to be a millet field).
270
Interview with Two Real Estate Developers (insert interview source, and location) (April 30, 2018), supra note
262 (in a typical social housing project, the government and private financial institutions combine forces to make
mortgages available to prospective purchasers. The banks agree to loan money at comparatively moderate rates of
interest and the government agrees to deduct the monthly payments directly from the borrowers’ paychecks. This
means, of course, that only Nigeriens with regular paychecks, or who live overseas together a wafer-thin slice of
Niger’s population can take advantage of the programs); see KORLING, supra note 20, at 79 (arguing Niger claims
that provision of housing for the poor is a key to poverty reduction but in fact has provided exceedingly little that is
accessible to the poor).
271
See Interview with Two Real Estate Developers (insert interview source, and location)
(April 28, 2018), supra note 262 (arguing that once they have formal title in hand, they have no fear that farmers
will be able to challenge their ownership of land).
272
Meyer, supra note 20, at 235; see Interview with Former Gamkalle Resident and His Friend (May 5, 2018), supra
note 208 (arguing that “land has become money”); Interview with Insurance Executive, Niamey, Republic of Niger,
(May 5, 2018) (arguing “land was religious; now it is money”).
95
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
D.
Summary
Niamey was created during the colonial era on land expropriated from the nearby
villages of Gamkale and Goudel. As the city’s population steadily grew, the colonial
government expropriated and subdivided land on its periphery–land that the French considered
vacant–to provide residences for its functionaries. Once the land was subdivided, it was subject
to the Code Napoléon. However, the scale of this conversion was modest; most rural people
were unaffected, and their lives continued as before.
Niger’s post-colonial governments carried on in a manner similar to the French. As
Niamey’s population growth accelerated, the state expropriated and converted larger swaths of
surrounding land, primarily still from the domains of Goudel and Gamkale. At times,
population growth outstripped the government’s ability to subdivide land, and so informal
settlements began to appear on what had been agricultural land.
Starting in the 1990s, democratization, economic liberalization, and decentralization,
combined with accelerating population growth in Niamey, led to a dramatic increase in the
city’s expansion and an accompanying flood of land conversions from fields to suburbs.
Various sources of authority–the CUN, central government ministries, local government
officials, and chiefs–vied with one another for authority over peri-urban land transactions and
attendant spoils. However, beginning in 2010, most of the governmental actors were shoved
to the side by the entrance of private land developers, who formed mafia-like networks in
cahoots with high government officials. Suddenly, all limits to peri-urban land development
vanished and a scramble for profits ensued. Developers and speculators began purchasing,
subdividing, titling and registering formerly agricultural lands at a blistering pace, sometimes
scores of kilometers outside the city. The private developers had no reason to care about poor
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
96
people which included the peasant farmers selling their ancestral lands. The government of
Niger claims they provide “social housing” to meet the needs of the poor, but in fact only
comparatively well-off Nigeriens are eligible to participate.
The next section explores who wins and who loses as a result of Niger’s peri-
urban transformation.
V.
Winners and Losers When Peri-Urban Land is Transformed from
Customary to Formal
The physical and legal transformation of peri-urban land around Niamey produces
winners and losers.
273
In general, the winners are those with power and wealth who take
advantage of the transition to increase their bounty.
274
The losers are peasant farmers whose
livelihoods disappear and who forfeit the historical and spiritual foundations that have until
now have provided order and meaning to their lives.
275
A.
Winners
Among scholars, it is a generally accepted nostrum that legal transformations in poor
countries benefit elites.
276
The reason is obvious: elites are better positioned to shape the
details of the new legal rules to serve their own interests.
277
Once the new rules are in place,
273
See HAGBERG, supra note 60, at 102 (arguing peri-urban land sales always produce winners and losers and that
rural people are usually the losers); see SHIPTON, supra note 8, at 144 (arguing early practitioners of land
privatization and titling in Kenya, which was a precursor to such efforts across sub-Saharan Africa, assumed
“energetic or rich Africans will be able to acquire more land and bad or poor farmers less, creating a landed and
landless class” and that “[t]his is a normal step in the evolution of a country”).
274
See Beacon Mbiba and Marie Huchzermeyer, supra note 2 (arguing local elites including officials, politicians and
traditional authorities often control land entitlements); Falk, supra note 171, at 1 (arguing land tenure reform always
ends up redistributing land from the poor to the rich); Polavarapu, supra note 104, at 98 (arguing that in Botswana
land tenure security is enjoyed only by the “rich and legally adroit”); COTULA, ET. AL., supra note 168, at 3
(arguing “elites claim land that isn’t theirs when they know registration is coming”).
275
See supra notes _ and accompanying text.
276
See Korling, supra note 20, at 78 (arguing in Niger urban policy and investment always serves elites); SHIPTON,
supra note 8 (arguing when land is converted from customary control to freehold title, “the best-informed and best-
connected people” benefit); Ubink, Tenure Security, supra note 57, at 222.
277
See Njoh, supra note 27, at 542 (arguing changes in zoning laws usually protect the rights and privileges of the
wealthy).
97
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
they have the necessary knowledge, capital, and connections to consolidate their advantages
before less informed societal actors become aware of the shift.
278
The transformation of land
law in peri- urban Niger is a case in point.
279
1.
Private Real Estate Developers and Investors and the
Government Officials with Whom They Collaborate
Private developers have emerged as the biggest winners in the conversion of peri-urban
land. At the top of the developer pyramid are the leaders of the mafia-like networks that have
infiltrated and dominated all levels of the state apparatus, and who have amassed fortunes by
converting large swaths of agricultural land into house plots.
280
But those land kingpins are
not the only private real estate actors who have thrived as a result of the transition.
Lower tiers of private developers have gotten into the game. Companies are forming
in Niamey to build the social housing developments around the city’s periphery.
281
Some
complain that their profit margins are thin. However, the recent profusion of these project
indicate that they are generating profits.
282
A third tier of wealthy elites benefit from the conversion of peri-urban land. These are
the wealthy El Hadji merchants from the city who until now have had few options for
diversifying their investments within Niger.
283
They are moving into land speculation, buying
large tracts of undeveloped agricultural property, sometimes twenty or more kilometers from the
278
See JIMU, supra note 2, at 7 (arguing that in African contexts urban actors seeking land can take advantage of
the poverty and ignorance of rural sellers).
279
See Njoh, supra note 27, at 542; see infra Part V.B.
280
See Issaka, supra note 1 (arguing certain private developers of peri-urban land have become more powerful than
governmental actors).
281
See supra note _.
282
See Issaka, supra note 1 (arguing corporations have entered the land development market and have made
substantial profits).
283
Id.; Interview with El Hadji Merchant (insert interview source, and location) (May 4, 2018), supra note 263.
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
98
city.
284
Different merchants employ different strategies. Once they have established titled
ownership of the land, many subdivide it into plots even if they intend to sit on it until Niamey
grows closer and the value of the plots increases.
285
Some intend to sell the plots piecemeal to
other smaller investors, or even to potential residents.
286
Still others have grander plans to move
into the business of real estate development by constructing the social housing projects described
above.
287
Whatever the details of their development strategies, wealthy businessmen based in the
capital are mobilizing to take advantage of the shift to private ownership of land.
These private developers become so successful partly by collaborating with government
officials who can claim formal authority over land transactions. There is still lively competition
among the governmental actors to determine whose authority will prevail, but as the competition
plays out it is clear that many are prospering. They formed corrupt symbiotic relationships that
strengthened their claims to authority over government institutions and, simultaneously,
produced significant private wealth.
288
Amidst this struggle for legitimacy and advantage among multifarious organs of the
state apparatus, traditional chiefs – historically a resilient and adaptable group
289
-- have found
284
See Interview with El Hadji Merchant (insert interview source, and location) (May 4, 2018), supra note 263
(describing his speculative investment in peri-urban land outside Niamey).
285
Id.
286
Id.
287
Id.
288
It should be noted that there is another class of people, who will be mentioned only in this note, that both win and
lose as a result of the symbiotic relationship between major real estate developers and corrupt governmental
officials. They are civil servants of moderate means who are searching for housing in the vicinity of Niamey. They
are winners because the entry of private developers on the peri-urban scene has increased the number of houses and
house plots available for purchase. See Meyer, supra note 1 (arguing Niger’s efforts to create housing and financing
for civil servants has worked). They are losers because the resulting neighborhoods and houses are often poorly
planned and constructed; See also Issaka, supra note 1. Because the developers are in cahoots with the government
officials, they can maximize profits by making roads too narrow for fire trucks, eschewing drainage infrastructure,
and failing to reserve space for public utilities. Id. With regulators looking the other way, they also save money and
increase profits by constructing homes using substandard materials. Id.
289
See Kelley at note 8 & 9.
99
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
opportunities to enhance their power and wealth.
290
With peri-urban land in high demand and
ambiguity concerning which state actors have the power to convert land from farms to
suburbs, rural Nigeriens have turned to chiefs, who retain much of their customary authority
over land in spite of the state’s efforts to weaken it.
291
Traditional chiefs’ approaches to peri-urban land transactions are as variable as those of the
state. Some village and canton chiefs expand their pocketbooks and their power by taking an
active role in facilitating the transfer of agricultural land to urban investors or developers.
292
In a
typical transaction, a developer from the city will approach a traditional chief whose rural
domain is 20 or more kilometers from the edge of Niamey’s existing suburbs.
293
The chief will
act as a broker, identifying a family patriarch willing to sell a large tract of family land;
sometimes with, sometimes without the extended family’s informed consent.
294
The chief may
take a finder’s fee that includes cash or a percentage of the house lots to be developed.
295
In
other instances, chiefs simply sell large tracts of undeveloped “chief’s lands” to investors even
though customarily they are guardians of that land and not owners.
296
290
See Janine M. Ubink, Courts and Peri-Urban Practice, supra note 194, at 28 (arguing in villages chiefs are major
actors in converting peri-urban land from agricultural to residential and that they often are the prime beneficiaries);
Benjaminsen, et.al., supra note 157, at 31 (arguing land shortages combined with increasing desire to formalize land
rights has provided a financial boon to traditional chiefs).
291
See COTULA ET. AL., supra note 168, at 12 (arguing land titling schemes in Africa did not work well, which
led to increases in chiefs’ power over land).
292
Interview with Retired Office Worker (April 28, 2018), See supra note 262 (recounting his purchase of plots of
land that were endorsed by canton chiefs).
293
Interview with Two Real Estate Developers (April 30, 2018), See supra note 262 (arguing their social housing
project, located approximately 30 kilometers outside Niamey, began with a purchase of land from farmers);
Interview with Former Mayor of Niamey Commune 5 (May 2, 2018), See also supra note 180 (arguing most peri-
urban land sales begin when a buyer approaches the head of a family).
294
See Janine M. Ubink, Courts and Peri-Urban Practice, supra note 194, at 37 (arguing chiefs in Ghana sometimes
connive with family elders to sell land out from under the control of extended families).
295
Interview with Retired Office Worker (April 28, 2018), See supra note 262 (arguing that when land is
subdivided, the chiefs always get their cut and providing the example of Niamey’s Haro Banda neighborhood, where
20% of all the newly created plots were divided among chiefs and government officials); See also Motcho, supra
note 48, at 7 (arguing chiefs have become central actors in suburbanization and that they profit by, among other
things, receiving compensation in the form of parcels).
296
See Bron-Saidatou, supra note 26, at 10, 27 (arguing under customary law chiefs are guardians of undeveloped
land, not owners); see also Interview with Canton Chief of Koure (May 3, 2018), supra note 100 (claiming
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
100
Even chiefs who do not take an active role in selling or developing peri-urban land
benefit from the transactions, at least in the short term. When investors or developers arrive in
the village and come to agreement with a family patriarch, the chief, for a fee, will create a
written document referred to as a detention coutumiere (customary holding).
297
That document
represents the developer’s or investor’s first step in the long and tortuous process (one that is
simpler for the land development kingpins with political connections)
298
of obtaining full,
individual ownership and registered title over the land.
299
In theory, the chief investigates the
transaction before granting the detention coutumiere, ensuring that the seller has a legitimate
claim over the land and that the seller’s family, many of whom may claim primary or secondary
rights in land, approve of the sale.
300
However, as described in Part V.B.1. below, the sales often
proceed without the extended family’s knowledge or acquiescence.
incorrectly that in pre-colonial Niger all land “belonged” to canton chiefs and that in recent time some village
chiefs have claimed ownership of land, obtained title, and sold it to developers); Interview with a Highly Placed
Official in Niger’s Ministry of the Environment and of Durable Development (May 11, 2018), See The World
Factbook at note 20 (arguing village chiefs in Niger claim ownership of vast tracts and “profit personally from the
sales”); Ubink, Courts and Peri-Urban Practice, supra note 194, at 30 (arguing chiefs in Ghana wrongly claim they
have the right to displace individual users of land and either sell it or lease it to strangers); Joseph Blocher, Building
on Custom: Land Tenure Policy and Economic Development in Ghana, Yale Hum. Rts. & Dev. L. J. 166, 168-169
(2006) (note) (arguing chiefs sometimes sell land “out from under” users); COTULA, ET. AL., supra note 168, at
27 (arguing chiefs sell land they do not own).
It should be noted that at least some chiefs take a hard line against the sale of peri-urban land to outsiders.
For example, the chef de canton of Hamdallaye, a town a half-hour drive out the Fillingue Road from Niamey,
claims he has steadfastly refused to authorize sales of customary agricultural land to investors or developers.
Interview with Hamdallaye Canton Chief (May 1, 2018), supra note 17. He also uses his traditional authority and
prestige to prevent his subjects from circumventing his authority and seeking authorization from the local mayor’s
office. Id. However, this reluctance to permit land conversion appears not to be well grounded in formal law and
is the exception rather than the rule. See Interview with Canton Chief of Koure (May 3, 2018), supra note 100
(arguing that he lacks authority to prevent land sales); Interview with Former Mayor of Niamey Commune 5
(May 2, 2018), supra note 180 (arguing canton chiefs lack authority to block land sales, even in rural areas).
297
See Korling at note 1 (mentioning detention coutumere), (arguing chiefs often charge 5,000 FCFA to issue
certificates of sale for village land).
298
See generally Meyer, supra notes 20; see also Korling, supra note 20; Interview with Former Mayor of Niamey
Commune 5, supra note 180.
299
See Bron-Saidatou, supra note 26, at 24 (describing the process of formalizing land).
300
Meyer, supra note 20, at 190. See generally Kelly, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8; Interview with Canton
Chief of Koure, supra note 100 (arguing chiefs preside over historical examinations to determine who has rights to
agricultural lands).
101
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
Whether or not the chief thoroughly vets the land sale, he receives his fee and thus becomes a
short-term winner in the conversion of land from fields to suburbs.
301
B.
Losers
1.
Immediate Losers: Secondary Rights Holders
When a land developer or speculator purchases a plot of agricultural land located in a
peri-urban area – usually from a family patriarch or chief
302
– the complicated customary
law bundle of nested, contingent, secondary rights that heretofore determined access to that
land
303
instantaneously vanishes.
304
Rural people who depend on secondary rights in land
find themselves with nothing.
Women in rural communities are a prime example.
305
Among rural Nigeriens, women do
not customarily have the right to inherit or control agricultural land, however, this does not mean
that they entirely lack rights in the lands controlled by their fathers, husbands, or brothers.
306
As
described above, women normally enjoy the right to enter land to harvest medicinal herbs,
301
See Meyer, supra note 20, at 190, 252 (arguing chiefs extract fees for approving land sales); Korling, supra note
20, at 125. Although the chiefs are “short-term” winners, one can speculate that their authority, which is practically
and spiritually rooted in the community’s lands, will wither as the chiefs convert the community land to individually
owned parcels. See generally Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8; Becker, supra note 104; SHIPTON, supra
note 8; Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra note 15.
302
See Ubink, Courts and Peri-Urban Practice, supra note 194 at 37 (arguing chiefs in Ghana sometimes connive
with family elders to sell land out from under the control of extended families); see also Interview with Former
Mayor of Niamey Commune 5, supra note 180; Korling, supra note 20, at 106 (arguing land sales on the edge of the
city usually start when a buyer approaches the head of a family).
303
See Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 102, at 682; SHIPTON, supra note 8, at 309; Becker, supra note 104;
Chimhown & Woodhouse, supra note 104; Polavarapu, supra note 104; Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra
note 9, at 1007, 1015.
304
See Chimhowu & Woodhouse, supra note 104, at 347-8 (arguing land titling often extinguishes secondary
“safety-net” rights such as wood gathering); see also Ubink, Tenure Security, supra note 57, at 222 (arguing titling
schemes often ignore secondary rights holders); COTULA ET AL., supra note 168, at 18 (arguing land titling often
leads to loss of secondary rights by women and pastoralists); Polavarapu, supra note 104, at 114 (arguing that
“nested rights” disappear when land is turned into a commodity).
305
Polavarapu, supra note 104, at 99-100.
306
See Polavarapu, supra note 104, at 111 (describing women’s secondary land rights under pre-colonial customary
law in Botswana); see Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 682.
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
102
collect straw, or plant a small garden.
307
These rights in land are not merely at the sufferance of
their husbands and male relatives; they are part of a finely-honed, well understood cultural and
spiritual complex.
308
If a male to denies or violate a woman’s customary rights, he will bring
shame on himself and his family, and the spirits tied to the land may sanction him.
309
Later-born men can be frozen out when their older brothers or uncles sell the family
lands.
310
As described in Part III. A., the family patriarch typically acts in the role of caretaker or
trustee for the extended family’s lands.
311
This means that a later-born man must seek the
patriarch’s approval before clearing or cultivating a new plot, but it does not mean that the
patriarch in any sense owns the family lands.
312
However, if the patriarch sells the land to an
outsider, the land becomes governed by state law, not customary law. Thus, the later-born
man’s access rights suddenly disappear,
313
whether or not the patriarch decides to share the
financial proceeds from the sale.
314
Customary slaves – a group most Nigeriens prefer not to discuss
315
– also lose their
culturally enforceable secondary rights in land when it is sold to developers or investors. It is
beyond the scope of this article to discuss the complicated bundle of Nigerien social categories
307
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 682.
308
See Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 683; see also Hagberg, supra note 60, at 104 (arguing those
who attempt to sell lineage lands in rural Burkina Faso risk sanction from the spirit world).
309
See Hagberg, supra note 60, at 10 (arguing earth priests and elders regard the earth “as a divinity and fear that the
violation of rituals may endanger not merely the individual’s well-being but community life in general”).
310
See Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1007 (arguing younger men in Nigerien villages have
limited rights to land access and are subject to the demands of the greater group and village Elders).
311
See id.
312
See id.
313
See Chimhowu & Woodhouse, supra note 104, at 347-8; see also Ubink, Tenure Security, supra note 57, at 222;
COTULA ET AL., supra note 168, at 18; Polavarapu, supra note 104, at 114.
314
JIMU, supra note 2, at 363 (arguing some sellers of customary land spend the proceeds on frivolity).
315
See Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1012 (arguing Nigerien government officials deny that
slavery exists in Niger).
103
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
inexactly lumped together under the English word “slave” or the French word esclave.
316
It must
suffice to say that under Nigerien customary law, slaves have a culturally enforceable right to
demand of village founders the use of sufficient agricultural lands to feed themselves and their
families.
317
In some villages, slave lineages have been cultivating tracts of land for generations,
land they do not control, but to which they have culturally enforceable access rights.
318
Under
custom, a patriarch that unceremoniously ejected a slave from agricultural lands would bring
shame on his lineage.
319
If, on the other hand, the patriarch sells the family land cultivated by
the slave, the culturally defined and enforceable rights described above simply vanish.
320
Once
the transaction is complete, the legal context instantaneously morphs: customary law holds its
relevance and “ownership” instantaneously vests in the individual who holds the piece of paper
reflecting title.
2. Long Term Losers
a. Those Who Depend on Customary Land for Livelihoods
For secondary rights holders, the loss resulting from the legal conversion of land from
custom to formal state law are sudden and dramatic. For primary rights holders, the losses
become apparent over time.
Imagine, for example, a village patriarch in a peri-urban zone sells all or much of his
family’s ancestral lands to a developer or speculator. Assume he obtained some form of
316
See id. at 1013-16.
317
See id. at 1017, 1022 (arguing Nigerian custom requires nobles to make agricultural land available to slave, but
in adopting western notions of land law, they can abandon this.)
318
See id. at 1034.
319
Id. at 1032.
320
Kelley, Unintended Consequences, supra note 9, at 1032.
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
104
permission from the sale from all or most of the heads of household in his lineage, though that is
not always the case.
321
Assume also that he receives a large amount of money in exchange for the land. I have
heard of one such transaction for which the purchaser paid the equivalent of $20,000
322
- a
substantial fortune in a country where most people live off of less than two dollars per day.
323
The money rarely lasts. In African locales, where peri-urban ancestral land is being sold to
developers, stories abound of patriarchs who spend the proceeds on la belle vie: drink, women,
and flashy possessions.
324
In Niger, a country where most rural people profess and practice
Islam and live sober, acetic lives,
325
the money may not go to alcohol and high living but
instead to satisfy the lineage’s pent-up demand for life’s necessities.
326
Young men who have
delayed marriage because they lack money for a bride price payment require financial backing
from the patriarch.
327
Family members living in grass huts require the construction of more
expensive banco houses with metal roofs.
328
Linage members who have been making due
321
See Blocher, supra note 296, at 168-9 (arguing chiefs in Ghana sometimes sell land out from under its rightful
users); see also Ubink, supra note 57, at 216 (similar); Bron-Saidatou, supra note 26, at 127 (arguing chiefs in Niger
do not own communal land but sometimes sell it without consultation).
322
Interview with Canton Chief of Koure, supra note 100 (arguing purchases of rural land in Koure, near Niamey,
sometimes amount to $10,000 or $20,000, a huge amount in Niger).
323
See Niger: Country Profile, WORLD HEALTH ORGANIZATION, available at
https://www.who.int/hac/crises/ner/background/profile/en (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) (reporting that over 60% of
Niger’s population lives with less than $1 a day). See also Country Reports on Human Rights Practices for 2015:
Niger, U.S. DEPT OF STATE (Jan. 20, 2015), available at https://2009-
2017.state.gov/j/drl/rls/hrrpt/humanrightsreport/index.htm?year=2015&dlid=252713 (last visited Sept. 27, 2019)
(reporting that in 2011, 48.2% of Niger’s population lived under the poverty income level of $1.70 a day).
324
See JIMU, supra note 2, at 38 (arguing most proceeds from land sales in Malawi are spent on “beer, prostitutes,
and pot,” and on general “conspicuous consumption”).
325
Kelley, Exporting Western Law to the Developing World, supra note 134. My characterization of Nigeriens
leading sober and ascetic lives is based on my years of experience and observation in rural communities there.
326
Interview with Canton Chief of Koure, supra note 100. See also Becker, supra note 104, at 120 (arguing some
sellers of ancestral land in Mali, a predominantly Muslim country, spend lavishly by giving gifts and offering their
friends rides in their new cars); JIMU, supra note 2, at 312-3 (arguing in Malawi land sales are often motivated by
practical financial concerns such as the payment of school fees, medical bills, bride-wealth payments, or tombstones
for dead relatives, though some of these justifications are “after-the-fact rationalizations.”)
327
Interview with Canton Chief of Koure, supra note 100.
328
I base this statement on personal knowledge of Nigerien friends who live in the U.S. and who send home
remittances so their relatives can switch from grass to banco.
105
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
with donkey carts feel the urgent need for motorcycles.
329
And, of course, the sale of
agricultural land means that the lineage’s ability to grow its own staple crops diminishes or
disappears, so they must purchase their grain at the market if they are to avoid starvation.
330
The small fortune disappears quickly.
331
When the money is gone, rural Nigeriens have no place else to turn. Niger has no
equivalent of mid-20
th
century Detroit or Chicago where former agricultural workers can
migrate to seek factory jobs.
332
Even if such jobs existed, the former subsistence farmers
would have no relevant skills to offer, since the vast majority are illiterate.
333
In short, when
the proceeds from the sale of ancestral lands run out, rural people will suffer.
334
329
Interview with Canton Chief of Koure, supra note 100.
330
See JIMU, supra note 2, at 71 (arguing that in Malawi the conversion of peri-urban land led to declines in food
production and increased poverty and insecurity for rural people).
331
Interview with a Highly Placed Official in Niger’s Ministry of the Environment and of Durable Development,
supra note 258 (arguing peasant farmers are “selling their patrimony” and that in many cases the money they receive
only lasts for months or years). It should be noted that counter-examples exist. There are instances where those
who sell their ancestral land invest wisely or start small businesses and prosper. JIMU, supra note 2, at 7 (arguing
some sellers of ancestral lands in Malawi use the proceeds to start a small business or obtain a commercial driving
license and prosper, though most spend the money quickly). Of the many Nigeriens I have interviewed over the
years, I have met one who prospered as a result of land sales. He was from the village of Goudel. Niger’s
government expropriated much of his family’s agricultural land over the decades. After the start of democratization
in the early 1990s, the government tried to compensate him and similarly situated Goudel farmers by granting them
a share of the undeveloped suburban house plots that had been carved out of their old fields. This man sold many of
those house plots and used the cash to buy a bar in Niamey. Over the following decades, the bar grew into a small
empire of bars, nightclubs, hotels, tourist businesses, transport, and real estate holdings. However, as the text
indicates, such economic success stories are the exception, not the rule.
332
See SHIPTON, supra, note 8, at 144 (arguing Kenya lacked the industry to create jobs for people made landless by
land titling; see also JIMU, supra note 2, at 7 (arguing wage jobs were not available for Malawi citizens rendered
landless).
333
The World Factbook (Niger), U.S. Cent. Intelligence Agency, available at https://
www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/ng.html (last visited Sept. 27, 2019) (reporting 19.1% of
Nigeriens over the age of 15 are literate).
334
Interview with Canton Chief of Koure, supra note 100 (arguing Nigerien farmers who well their land “end up
poor”); Interview with Former Mayor of Niamey’s Central Government, in Niamey, Niger (May 11, 2018 (arguing
proceeds of rural land sale go for weddings, trips, and motorcycles, and “then they’re left with nothingthey
become beggars and thieves”); Interview with Judge, in Niamey, Niger (May 9, 2018 (arguing after rural land sales
in Niger, “pretty soon the money is gone and they [the farmers] starve”). See also Jimu, supra note 2, at 338
(arguing land sellers in Malawi who cannot find wage labor end up destitute); Falk, supra note 171, at 1 (arguing
that in African contexts landlessness is synonymous with poverty).
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
106
b. Those Who Define Themselves, Their Communities, Their
History, and Their Religion with Reference to Ancestral Land
For rural people in peri-urban Niger, hunger is not the only consequence of land sales
because land represents more than just a means of food production.
335
The legal
transformation of ancestral land into a salable commodity – in effect converting land into
money
336
– effaces the historical, cultural, and spiritual legacy that until now had given shape
and strength to rural Nigerien communities.
337
Rural Nigeriens may be desperately poor by international standards,
338
but overall,
they lead lives of honor and purpose.
339
They take pride in offering food and shelter to
travelers.
340
If a stranger wants to extend their stay in the village, the village chief or other
lineage heads will accord him access to enough land to feed himself and his family.
341
Villagers look after one another, periodically gathering together to cultivate and harvest the
fields of sick or recently deceased members of the community or to build huts for newlywed
couples.
342
Respect for age is common.
343
Theft is rare.
344
Rural Nigeriens generally live in
peace, mediating their differences in ways that Americans should emulate: they gather in
public, talk things through, and endeavor to find compromise, a modus vivendi that permits
them to navigate the difficult business of living together amidst some of the harshest
335
See supra Part III.A
336
Interview with Former Gamkalle Resident and His Friend, supra note 208; Interview with Former Mayor of
Niamey’s Central Government, supra note 334.
337
See Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 667, 710, n. 135; see also SHIPTON, supra note 8, at 14.
338
See Human Development Reports, supra note 19; The World Factbook (Niger), supra note 19.
339
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 667.
340
See id. (arguing visitors to Nigerien villages “are plied with food and gifts”).
341
See id. at 666 (describing a family making agricultural land available to an outsider who wished to settle in the
village).
342
See id. (arguing in the Zarma language of Niger, the word bogu describes communal labor, often undertaken on
behalf of a villager in need and is the rough equivalent of “barn raising” in English).
343
Id. at 667; see also SHIPTON, supra note 8, at 14 (arguing respect for age is common among the Luo people of
Kenya).
344
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 673.
107
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
geographic and climatic conditions on earth.
345
These positive attributes of Nigerien rural society arise out of an undivided complex of
spiritual, historical, and cultural beliefs in which land, including individuals’ rights in and
obligations toward land, is a central tenet.
346
Land gives shape to rural peoples’ identities and
sense of self.
347
Even considering the recent increase of Islamic influence, most rural
Nigeriens believe their ancestors made pacts with the spirits who control the land and that
those spirits, along with the spirits of their ancestors continue to watch over the decisions and
actions villagers take.
348
A young man in the village avoids unruly behavior because he has
been raised that way, but also because he does not want to be the one to spark the spirits’
wrath and thereby diminishes the village’s barka.
349
He accepts his father’s or uncle’s
decisions about which plot of land to cultivate, and about when he can begin cultivating for
his own rather than the extended family’s account, because to object, to rebel, would injure
not only his family but would insult the original land spirits and the spirits of his ancestors.
350
That same young man, once his elders have accorded him a portion of the family land for
345
See id. at 710. I am fully aware that depicting rural life in Niger in this way risks sparking the ire of scholars who
condemn as simplistic the colonial and post-colonial thesis that rural Africans live in harmony with themselves and
nature. See generally Mark Davidheiser, Harmony, Peacemaking, and Power: Controlling Processes and African
Mediation, 23 CONFLICT RESOL. Q. 281, 282-6 (2006) (summarizing various critiques of the “harmony thesis”).
But ire be damned. Yes, rural Nigeriens sometimes vie with one another over resources. Yes, intractable conflicts
sometimes arise within and among villages that can only be resolved with outside intervention. Yet, the cooperative
practices described above, and the overall peaceful, positive nature of Nigerien villages, is both an ideal toward
which Nigeriens strive and an empirical fact.
346
See Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 704 (arguing land is a key element in maintaining village
harmony); see also Becker, supra note 104, at 115 (arguing customary land helps “define cultural identity through
social relations”).
347
Shipton, supra note 8, at 110-11, 17 (arguing that the Luo people of Kenya view themselves as belonging to the
land and, through the medium of the land, belonging to other people and that land is “tied up with some of the most
intimate, emotionally charged dimensions of personhood and pride”).
348
See Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 647-8.
349
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 704; see also Hagberg, supra note 60, at 99 (arguing village leaders
in Burkina Faso consider the land “as a divinity and fear that the violation of rituals may endanger not merely the
individual’s well-being but community life in general”).
350
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 704; JIMU, supra note 2, at 8 (arguing land is a symbolic medium
through which living people connect with their ancestors and their traditions); Blocher supra note 296, at 174
(arguing trust and honor can play a vital role in consistent land practices leading to stability and efficiency).
Kelley Syracuse J. Int. L. & Comm. Vol. 47.1.
108
cultivation, will avoid waste and certainly avoid sale, because he understands that interest in
the land is shared not only by his living relations, but by those who lived before and those
members of the family and community yet unborn.
351
When land is titled and sold out of the community, those beliefs that tie together history,
spirituality and law disappear.
352
If the spirits and their influence are displaced by a legal title
– a piece of paper filed in a distant town saying an outsider now owns the property – that
young man can take his proceeds, (assuming he is not struck by lightning or otherwise quickly
felled by illness or other misfortune)
353
and ignore concerns about the ancestors’ wrath.
354
He
can disregard the wishes of his father, his lineage head, and his village chief, because they no
longer have influence over his and his children’s future access to land.
355
That issue will be
decided not by village elders, but by who can decode the foreign, formal legal process, obtain
the necessary piece of paper and properly register it in the distant cadaster.
In sum, land is an essential aspect of the social, spiritual, historical and legal complex that
provides structure and meaning to rural Nigerien communities. Removing land from this
351
See Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8; see also Njoh, supra note 27, at 555 (arguing land sales are
unthinkable in Nigerien customary law because those who control land hold it act as custodians for future
generations); Blocher, supra note 296, at 174 (arguing chiefs in Ghana hold land in trust for the living, the dead, and
the not yet born).
352
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 704-7; see Korling, supra note 20, at 133-34 (arguing authority in
Nigerien rural communities is tied to land and those who alienate land lose their authority); Becker, supra note 104,
at 115 (arguing “Where land is not a commodity, its non-market values define cultural identity through social
relations. When and where land sales occur marks a fundamental agrarian change that breaks cultural ties to the
land…”).
353
See SHIPTON, supra note 8, at 159 (arguing that in Kenya those who title an alienate family land “expose
themselves to the wrath of the spirits”).
354
Becker, supra note 104, at 121 (arguing in Mali, land sales are leading to a decline in cooperative spirit of the
ethnic group’s values). See also Ubink, supra note 57, at 223 (arguing studies of peri-urban land sales show
abundant evidence of high social cost, especially for the poor).
355
Kelley, Squeezing Parakeets, supra note 8, at 70; see also Becker, supra note 104, at 121. (arguing land sales in
peri- urban Mali contribute to “a decline in the cooperative spirit of the ethnic group’s values” that will “radically
change the village in the next generation”).
109
Death of Custom:
Winners and Losers in the Legal Transformation of Peri-Urban Land in Niger
complex will profoundly disrupt a system that has permitted Nigeriens to persevere for many
generations amidst extraordinarily difficult conditions.
356
356
See Becker, supra note 104, at 115 (arguing land conversion creates “new territories with new boundaries, new
rules and new authorities claiming new legitimacy to control access” leading to “a profound transformation of
society”); SHIPTON, supra note 8, at 128-29 (arguing land titling in Kenya threatens to upset the deeply rooted
land-related traditions and may lead to social disruption).